Exploring the uncharted influence of family social capital in entrepreneurial ecosystems

Samuel Wayne Appleton (Center for Family and Young Enterprises, University of Bergamo, Bergamo, Italy)
Christodoulos Pavlou (Faculty of Business, The American University of Beirut - Mediterraneo, Pafos, Cyprus)

Journal of Family Business Management

ISSN: 2043-6238

Article publication date: 20 June 2024

284

Abstract

Purpose

The purpose of this research is to develop theory, thereby attending to the existing knowledge gap regarding the impact of family firms on entrepreneurial ecosystems (EEs). Reducing such a gap is both timely and relevant given the ubiquity of family firms across the globe and the lack of theoretical development at the intersection of EE and family firm literatures. By employing social capital theory in a propositional theorizing approach, this article presents unique propositions that enrich current understanding of the EE phenomenon.

Design/methodology/approach

Our method adopts a three-step propositional theorizing approach. The first step outlines our conceptualization, drawing on social capital theory and identifying multiple levels of analysis pertaining to EEs and family firms. The second step precisely identifies the constructs used for the theorization process, drawing upon relevant literature. The third step involves proposition building, which produces our findings.

Findings

As a result of our propositional theorizing method, we developed 10 theoretical propositions to explain interactions between family members, nonfamily entrepreneurs, family firms and new ventures in the EE, thereby focusing on the social elements of the EE and reducing its conceptual complexity while extending the explanatory power of family social capital in the EE.

Research limitations/implications

Despite being increasingly relevant in research, policy and practice discourse, EEs remain under theorized. By theorizing in this context, we provide explanations of the mechanisms to explain social interactions between family members, nonfamily entrepreneurs, family firms and new ventures and how such interactions are likely to provide better access to the untapped resources in the EE. Furthermore, our theorization also identifies underexplored research areas paving the way for future scholars.

Practical implications

This article is relevant to practitioners and policymakers interested in creating balanced, inclusive and effective EE policies and interventions. Our theorization generates insights that complement a bottom-up approach where the state assumes a facilitating role for actors such as family firms to positively impact their EE. This research is both timely and necessary because, if unaddressed, it will lead to ineffective and potentially exclusionary policies and EE interventions.

Originality/value

We contribute to the literature by synthesizing the two domains and thereby advancing knowledge at the intersection of EE and family firm literatures. We strengthen the link between two burgeoning research areas through a propositional theorizing mode of theory development. Under the assumptions of a grand theory, social capital theory, we highlight the benefits that derive from social interactions in the EE between family firms and other EE actors.

Keywords

Citation

Appleton, S.W. and Pavlou, C. (2024), "Exploring the uncharted influence of family social capital in entrepreneurial ecosystems", Journal of Family Business Management, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print. https://doi.org/10.1108/JFBM-02-2024-0037

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2024, Samuel Wayne Appleton and Christodoulos Pavlou

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

During the last decade, the concept of entrepreneurial ecosystems (EEs) has received increasing attention from researchers, policymakers and practitioners (Malecki, 2018; Wurth et al., 2022). The popularity of EEs may be attributed to their potential in explaining why certain locations are able to foster and sustain productive entrepreneurship (Hruskova et al., 2022). This interest has led to the examination of how different organizational forms, such as social enterprises (Roundy, 2017; Thompson et al., 2018), multinational enterprises (Bhawe and Zahra, 2019; Ryan et al., 2020; Ratten, 2020), entrepreneurship support organizations (Bergman and McMullen, 2022; Hruskova et al., 2022) and family firms (Bichler et al., 2022; Benavides-Salazar et al., 2022), influence the functionality of EEs and by extension, productive entrepreneurship. Despite the ongoing research efforts, the EE concept remains undertheorized (Scheidgen, 2020; Spigel et al., 2020; Fotopoulos, 2023) and consequently a gap in knowledge concerns how EEs impact the presence and operations of EE actors, such as family firms (Cobben et al., 2023) and in turn, how those actors influence the EE (Wurth et al., 2022; Daniel et al., 2022).

Generally, a family may adopt multiple organizational forms to interact with its environment (De Massis et al., 2021), generating direct and indirect impacts on the net output of the economy (Memili et al., 2015). Whether this impact is positive or negative depends on the presence and intensity of various factors such as the levels of regional “Familiness” (Basco, 2015, 2024), socio-emotional wealth (SEW) (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007), family social capital (Arregle et al., 2007; Pearson et al., 2008; Stasa and Machek, 2022) and/or the family's stewardship of their environment (Madison et al., 2016). Sufficient levels of these factors enable distinct interactions between family firms and their environment, such as the development of long-standing relations/stakeholders (Röd, 2016), a heightened concern for their reputation (Campopiano and De Massis, 2015), a vested interest in their employees (Davis et al., 2010) and a general concern for their surroundings (Baù et al., 2019).

Although there is a consensus on family firms being contributors to socio-economic development (Basco, 2024; De Massis et al., 2021; Memili et al., 2015), it remains unclear precisely how family firms influence EEs and vice versa. Given that both EEs and family firms are viewed as sources of productive entrepreneurship, a lack of clarity limits current understanding regarding the potential synergies between the two. Embryonic research at the intersection of these two phenomena (Bichler et al., 2022; Benavides-Salazar et al., 2022; Cobben et al., 2023) indicate an incomplete knowledge gap (Sandberg and Alvesson, 2010). Albeit, what is clear is the role of social capital in both EEs (Pugh et al., 2019; Scheidgen, 2020; Theodoraki et al., 2018; Wurth et al., 2022) and family firms (Arregle et al., 2007; Pearson et al., 2008; Stasa and Machek, 2022). Wurth et al. (2022) identifies social capital as one of the “most prominent” (p. 26) theories in studying EEs, while family social capital is one of the prominent theories in the family firm literature (see Stasa and Machek, 2022 for a review). Thereby, it's an appropriate theory for addressing the gap at the intersection of both literatures. EE literature, typically focuses on studying high-growth entrepreneurship (Brown and Mason, 2017; Spigel et al., 2020) and family firm literature, which overlooks the relevance of EEs, as indicated by the absence of the term in a recent review of the field (Siaba and Rivera, 2024). In short, we answer the following research question: “How does social capital theory explain the interactions, their positive and/or negative effects, between family firms and entrepreneurial ecosystems at the macro, meso and micro levels?

To answer our research question, we adopt a three-step propositional theorizing process (Bacharach, 1989; Cornelissen, 2017; Cornelissen et al., 2021; Suddaby, 2010). The first step involves conceptualization, in which we utilize social capital theory through a multi-level model (Klein et al., 1999) and then outline the theoretical assumptions following the schematic variant of social capital theory. In the second step, we specify our constructs ensuring clarity and coherence across our model (Suddaby, 2010). In the final step, we infuse the theoretical logics from family social capital and EE social capital to develop 10 propositions.

By developing theoretical propositions concerning the interrelation between the social elements of the EE and family firms, this paper makes a theoretical contribution at the intersection of EE and family firm literatures. The key knowledge advancement lies in the conceptual shift of EE research to include the family firm as a key actor, responding to the calls of Welter et al. (2017) in embracing research of diverse types of entrepreneurship. In highlighting the role of the family firm, we explain how interactions between the EE and family firms enhance the creation of social and economic value through productive entrepreneurship (Wurth et al., 2022). By doing so, we simultaneously contribute to the family firm literature by extending existing research on the role of family firms in the EE (Bichler et al., 2022; Benavides-Salazar et al., 2022; Cobben et al., 2023). We also contribute to family social capital literature by adopting a schematic view providing a contingency to the prevailing instrumental view of family social capital (Stasa and Machek, 2022). In addition to our theoretical contributions, we also provide future research directions for scholars seeking to advance EE, family firm and social capital research.

The remainder of this study is organized as follows: The next section provides an overview of family firm research and EE literature. The third section explains our methodological approach. The fourth section presents our developed theoretical propositions. The concluding section includes our theoretical contributions, implications for policy and practitioners and future research directions.

2. Literature overview

2.1 Family firm research

Family firm research is based upon the overlap of two sociological systems, the family and the business (Holt et al., 2018). Since the 1980s, family firm research has grown in depth and breadth. At one point, family business research experienced definitional issues (Sharma et al., 1996), stalling the field's progress as a lack of consensus among the definition limits knowledge accumulation (Suddaby, 2010). However, the dominant definition remains to be the one formulated by three of the most prolific scholars in the field and is as follows:

… a business held or governed with the intention to shape and pursue the vision of the business held by a dominant coalition controlled by members of the same family or a small number of families in a manner that is potentially sustainable across generations of the family or the families (Chua et al., 1999, p. 25).

Family business research was then criticized for a lack of theory (De Massis et al., 2012). Since then, many theories have been applied to understanding the phenomenon of the family firm. To name but a few: agency theory (both principle-agent, principle-principle relationships) (Gomez-Mejia et al., 2001), the ability-willingness paradox (De Massis et al., 2014), long-term orientation (Lumpkin et al., 2010), familiness (Habbershon and Williams, 1999), SEW (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007) family social capital (Arregle et al., 2007; Pearson et al., 2008; Stasa and Machek, 2022) and stewardship theory (Madison et al., 2016).

In regard to family social capital theory, it is a potential source of competitive advantage for family firms over nonfamily firms and comes in three distinct instrumental forms: internal family social capital (Pearson et al., 2008; Arregle et al., 2007; Carr et al., 2011), organizational family social capital (Zahra, 2010) and external family social capital (Hadjielias et al., 2022). Generally, social capital explains particular family firm social relations derived from the overlap of family and business structures that create unique processes (Arregle et al., 2007), aiming to create multi-generational wealth (Habbershon et al., 2003).

2.2 Entrepreneurial ecosystems

EEs have emerged as a prominent concept in entrepreneurship research due to their promise in explaining why certain locations are able to foster and sustain productive entrepreneurship (Malecki, 2018; Wurth et al., 2022; Hruskova et al., 2022). Productive entrepreneurship is defined as “any entrepreneurial activity that contributes directly or indirectly to net output of the economy or to the capacity to produce additional output” (Baumol, 1993: p. 30). According to Rocha et al. (2021), the conceptual ambiguity and interpretive flexibility of EEs has led to the development of various expansive and specified definitions (See Table 1).

Our research adopts Spigel’s (2017) definition which conceptualizes EEs as:

A combination of social, political, economic, and cultural elements within a region that support the development and growth of innovative start-ups and encourage nascent entrepreneurs and other actors to take the risks of starting, funding, and otherwise assisting high-risk ventures (Spigel, 2017, p. 50).

We selected Spigel’s (2017) for two reasons. First, the definition explicates the interrelationships between EE elements and therefore acknowledges that EEs are heterogenous in their elements, processes and configurations. Second, the conceptualization of EE social elements as “the resources composed of or acquired through the social networks within a region” (Spigel, 2017: p. 53), are in alignment with the tenets of social capital theory which is employed by this study to theorize the interconnections between family firms and EEs.

Early EE research attempted to identify the recipe for a successful EE by developing several “laundry lists” (Stam, 2015, p. 1764) of EE elements from established ecosystems (Isenberg, 2010; Feld, 2012; Spigel, 2020). This approach however faced criticism as it failed to explicate what was cause and what was effect (Stam, 2015; Spigel, 2017), as it disregarded the contextual idiosyncrasies of each place (Welter et al., 2017) and the dynamic nature of ecosystems (Brown and Mason, 2017) as well as their internal heterogeneity (Scheidgen, 2020; Spigel, 2020). More recent EE research has attempted to address these shortcomings by acknowledging the heterogenous configurations and contextual idiosyncrasies of EEs. Despite the ongoing research efforts, the EE concept remains undertheorized (Scheidgen, 2020; Spigel et al., 2020; Fotopoulos, 2023) as it is still not clear how EEs impact the presence and operations of EE actors, such as family firms (Cobben et al., 2023) and in turn, how those actors influence the EE itself (Wurth et al., 2022; Daniel et al., 2022). This maybe due to a bias in EE literature which focuses on studying high-growth/high-tech firms while disregarding other organizational forms (e.g. family firms, social enterprises) and venture types (e.g. lifestyle, survival) (Neumeyer et al., 2019; Spigel et al., 2020; Wurth et al., 2022).

Integrating family firms into the EE theorization addresses such limitations as it aligns with the latest conceptual developments in the EE literature that focus on examining the contextual, structural and configurational heterogeneity of across and within EEs (Spigel, 2017; Roundy, 2017; Spigel and Harrison, 2018; Scheidgen, 2020) while responding to the calls for more diversity in entrepreneurship research (Welter et al., 2017). Our research thus challenges the existing narratives and conceptualizations that give primacy to the certain EE actors that are perceived to be inherently beneficial to the functionality of EEs, such as high-growth (Malecki, 2018; Bergman and McMullen, 2022; Hruskova et al., 2022) and paves the way in examining elements that were previously neglected from EE literature such as family firms.

By theorizing how EEs influence family firms, as well as how family firms influence productive entrepreneurship within an EE, this study improves understanding of EE dynamics and their associated complexities. This enables us to better understand how family firms may influence the EE through their unique resources and practices (Yilmaz et al., 2024), how they impact the EE's resilience (Hackler and Mayer, 2008; Eraydin et al., 2010; Roundy et al., 2017; Spigel and Harrison, 2018) and legitimacy (Suchman, 1995; Zimmerman and Zeitz, 2002; Spigel and Harrison, 2018), that are argued to be important traits of a functioning EE.

3. Methodology

Theory building can take many forms, such as propositional theorizing, configurational theorizing, process theorizing, perspectival theorizing, or meta-theorizing (Cornelissen, 2017; Cornelissen et al., 2021). In this paper we focus on propositional theorizing, defined as “a style of theorizing that elaborates basic contingencies (as propositions) that explain a topic” (Cornelissen et al., 2021, p. 7), which facilitates an answer to the posed research question by theorizing “a previously unexplored process or relationship” (Colquitt and Zapata-Phela, 2007: p. 1283) [1]. This process involved three steps. Firstly, conceptualization and explicating our theoretical assumptions based on social capital theory. The second step describes the construct development. The third step involved developing the propositions which can be found in Section 4.

3.1 Conceptualization and theoretic assumptions

The first step of propositional theorization is to ground the process in a broader theoretical framework (Cornelissen, 2017). Here we adopt social capital theory, which, since its inception (Banfield, 1958), has been significantly developed by seminal works (Bourdieu, 1987; Granovetter, 1995; Coleman, 1988). Consequently, social capital theory is able to explain a significant amount of behavior such as (to name but a few): networks (Burt, 1992), the formation of intellectual capital (Nahapiet and Ghoshal, 1998), entrepreneurial behavior (Gedajlovic et al., 2013), certain managerial tasks (Moran, 2005) and unique family influences on the firm (Arregle et al., 2007).

More specifically, in the entrepreneurship literature social capital has been employed to explore legitimacy and how it can be developed through the entrepreneur's own high-status (Khoury et al., 2013) or trusted references in the network (Packalen, 2007). Legitimacy has been acknowledged as a key element of entrepreneurial survival, growth and performance as it is directly linked with the practice of accessing resources (Zimmerman and Zeitz, 2002; Pollack et al., 2012; Lasrado et al., 2016; Fisher et al., 2016). Recent EE literature has stressed the need to utilize social capital to understand “not just [of] the resources present in networks or the nature of the ties between actors, but also the role of cultural factors like trust in how actors affect the relationships which drive the ecosystem” (Wurth et al., 2022, p. 24) and the importance of considering “different levels of aggregation” (p. 26). Thus, a multi-level approach of social capital (Payne et al., 2011) facilitates multi-level theorizing (Klein et al., 1999). Social capital via a multi-level theorization isolates the interactions on and between each level of analysis. We focus on the macro level (the ecosystem), the meso level (family firms and other firms such as new ventures in the EE) and the micro level (family members and other individuals in the EE).

Firstly, on the micro level, social capital holds an instrumental value for individuals to engage in interactions to generate social capital (Coleman, 1988; Burt, 1992). Within this logic, social capital is an outcome of interactions possessed by the individual, both internal and external to the organization (in this case the family firm). Through nurturing interactions with a wide range of individuals (in this case EE actors) results in an individual's connectivity, centrality and hierarchy in any given network (Burt, 1992).

Secondly, at the meso level, social capital theory captures the series of repeated interactions of the collective (in this case the family firm or the start-up), a close set of interactions over a sustained period, as a requisite to accessing the benefits of social capital (Bourdieu, 1987), which often leads to solidarity, trust and a shared identity (Coleman, 1988).

Thirdly, at the macro level, the observation concerns the social structures that influence and are influenced by social interactions (Sandefur and Lauman, 1998). For Portes (1998) and Granovetter (1995) an individual's behavior is mainly determined by the surrounding social structure. Social structures can be coercive mechanisms, rewarding and sanctioning members of the group, shaping the actions of the individual, attributing social capital as belonging more to the structure than the individual (Moran, 2005). This results in context specific shared schemas that influence subsequent interactions between the EE, family firms and other related actors. Enabling rationale to be developed explaining the interrelationships between family firms and the EE and specifically how this occurs through interactions with individuals, shaped by the family social capital's and the EE's schemas.

In summary, our framework assumes that individuals are driven by their own agency, while also acknowledging the social structures manifest an established shared schema, which exhibits characteristics such as sanctions, norms, expectations and tacit knowledge. These imposed characteristics govern future behavior but an individual has the agency to deviate from expectations (Long, 2011; Long and Matthews, 2011). Therefore, we explicate three governing assumptions: (1) interactions on one level influence the other levels of analysis (2) repeated interactions between actors form shared schemas and (3) shared schemas influence subsequent interactions between actors.

3.2 Construct development

Construct development is important for propositional theorizing (Cornelissen, 2017), since constructs are the building blocks of theory (Suddaby, 2010; Bacharach, 1989). Here, we define constructs as “simply robust categories that distill phenomenon into sharp distinctions that are comprehensible to a community of researchers” (Suddaby, 2010, p. 346). In order to maintain coherence with social capital theory, we isolate the social elements of the EE outlined by Spigel’s (2017) definition and take constructs from family social capital theory (Arregle et al., 2007; Pearson et al., 2008). A list of our constructs are included in Table 2. A diagram of our model, prior to the third step of our propositional theorizing, is included in Figure 1. In addition, an extensive range of references we grounded our constructs in, encapsulating their boundaries, interactions and meaning, are included in Appendix 2.

4. Theory development

As the third step of our propositional theorizing, we develop our propositions by drawing on the literature to develop our reasoning that culminates in our propositions as instructed by Cornelissen (2017).

4.1 How does the macro level and micro level interaction influence EE schema and the entrepreneur's social capital?

Within EEs, the social capital of entrepreneurs is seen as a vital systemic condition for a well-functioning EE (Stam, 2015). Thus, various EE actors offering entrepreneurship support services and leading ecosystem initiatives (e.g. governments and universities), lay a special emphasis on helping entrepreneurs to develop their networks and connections within an EE (Theodoraki et al., 2018; Pugh et al., 2019; Scheidgen, 2020). Participating to these support services and initiatives constitutes a more efficient and accelerated way for entrepreneurs to build, enhance and signal their social capital within an EE (Spigel and Harrison, 2018).

Importantly, social capital theory proposes that entrepreneurs in a network will be able to derive value (in this case the recognition of opportunities) from brokering information (Burt, 1992). However, such brokering opportunity is contingent upon an entrepreneur's position in an ecosystem and will depend on their power, centrality and hierarchy in relation to others (Burt, 1997). The better positioned an entrepreneur is in the EE, the better their brokering options are, in turn providing more information advantages, such as timely exposure to non-redundant information (Burt and Opper, 2020). The entrepreneur's position is contingent upon their power, centrality and hierarchy. An entrepreneur's position over time intertwines with the EE's schema, embodying both the EE coherence (shared values, solidarity and trust) and the history of interactions that has led to the schema's current state. The longer the entrepreneur has been participating in the EE the more likely their position will have improved, providing them with more network centrality. Also, the more coherent the entrepreneur is with the EE, the more the entrepreneur will be able to project, signal and communicate their own values thus increasing their alignment with the EE. Overall, long-standing entrepreneurs in the EE are more likely to receive more information for new opportunities, therefore we propose:

Proposition 1A.

The longer and more coherent an entrepreneur is with the EE's schema, the greater their access to resources from the EE.

A further benefit an entrepreneur may gain from a strong position in their EE is entrepreneurial legitimacy. This derives from their reputation and consequently their actions are perceived to be “desirable, proper, or appropriate” (Suchman, 1995, p. 574). For example, when an agent holds a high status in an industry, their actions are legitimized by other actors (Khoury et al., 2013). Furthermore, even entrepreneurs in a weaker position in the EE may establish their legitimacy if more centered actors are able to provide them with references (Packalen, 2007). Thus, the EE leads to more legitimacy for entrepreneurs and their ventures. Therefore, we propose:

Proposition 1B.

The longer and more coherent an entrepreneur is with the EE's schema; the more legitimacy is assigned to them and their new ventures.

Social capital is relevant in the creation of new ventures (Kreiser et al., 2013), but is not automatically productive and in some ways brings diminishing returns (Portes, 1998). In this case, once the opportunity has been recognized the entrepreneur's attention is better spent on other activities. Antagonizing this is the logic that sustaining social capital requires a significant amount of time, effort and resources (Coleman, 1988; Westlund and Bolton, 2003). Thus, the entrepreneur must recognize how much time, effort and resources are spent on EE interactions. Failure to recognize and successfully manage this may result in negative returns, otherwise known as unproductive social capital (Gedajlovic et al., 2013). Therefore, we propose:

Proposition 2.

An entrepreneur must be careful of the diminishing returns of social capital from the EE and the potential distractions of EE networking.

4.2 How do interactions between the Macro and Meso levels, i.e. the family firm's schema and the EE's schema affect the EE?

The family firm schema represents the internal family social capital on the firm level (Long, 2011) derived from the pattern of family interactions in the firm, which lead to unique characteristics such as long-term orientation (Zellweger and Sieger, 2010), SEW (Gómez-Meija et al., 2007), peculiar processes (Arregle et al., 2007) and shared history, values, trust and identity (Pearson et al., 2008). Thus, the family firm's schema interacts with the EE's schema and their objectives influence one another. Indeed, the family firm's interest may not always align with the EE's schema, and a family firm may deliberately attempt to shape the EE's schema to suit the family's needs. This is contingent upon the length of time the family firm has participated in the EE (following the logic of the proposition 1A and 1B).

When the family firm has a strong position in the EE, due to a long-standing participation, their network centrality provides enhanced information and EE legitimacy. However, it's well known that family firms are prone to risk-aversion as their age increases (Molly et al., 2012). This phenomenon will likely negatively impact the EE schema, as elucidated by Morck and Yeung (2003) in the business group and innovation context. Thus, a family firm's risk-aversion will negatively impact the EE as a family firm will seek to delegitimize entrepreneurial opportunities that are high risk, leading to counterproductive forms of entrepreneurship, rather than productive entrepreneurship. Hence:

Proposition 3.

A long-standing family firm in an EE can use their position to de-legitimize opportunities that they perceive as risky.

4.3 How does the EE's schema’, family firm's schema and individual family members interact with one another?

Family firm research has found that family firms are sometimes able to mitigate this risk-aversion, through specific behaviors such as transgenerational entrepreneurship (Cohen and Sharma, 2016). Naturally, because the next generation is less immersed in the existing family firm's schema than senior generation members, they are less likely to have network attachments that keep them entrenched in their existing networks (Hadjielias et al., 2022). Indeed, in this case, the next generation is free to combine benefits derived from both the family firm's schema and the EE's schema. From the family firm's schema, the next generation can gain advantages from the family's shared history, values and know-how on starting new ventures (Discua-Cruz et al., 2013), as well as financial and physical resources (Sharma, 2008). In turn, they can also use the family firm's legitimacy and informational advantages to create new ventures. From the EE's schema, the next generation members will gain the advantage of being informed of new entrepreneurial opportunities. In addition, they are perceived by others as more attractive to collaborate with due to their endowed reputation and accessibility to resources from the family firms. All these combined increases the likelihood of their success and consequently productive entrepreneurship. Hence the following proposition:

Proposition 4.

Next generation family members can utilize the family firm's schema as well as the EE's schema to increase the legitimacy and attraction of their new ventures to potential partners.

Moreover, in the absence of next generation members and a concentration of senior generation members, the attachment to the network heightens due to their long tenure, preference for the status quo (Cassia et al., 2012) and loyalty towards existing buyers and suppliers (De Massis et al., 2016). All of which are symptomatic of a constrained network, where contacts already know each other and there is an increasing amount of redundant information (Burt, 2002). In this situation the EE will suffer from a lack of diversity, which is required for productive entrepreneurship and resilience (Roundy et al., 2017). Hence:

Proposition 5.

When senior generation family members form a family firm's schema it becomes stagnant and lacks diversity required for an EE to foster productive entrepreneurship and ecosystem resilience.

Furthermore, if there is a balance of next generation members and senior generation members that comprise the family firm's schema, it is likely to produce the benefits that lead to the advantages of family social capital (Pearson et al., 2008). There are several specific advantages that benefit the EE and contribute to positive outputs, i.e. productive entrepreneurship. Firstly, intergenerational interactions produce cognitive diversity (Chirico et al., 2011), enriching the EE's resevoir of resources. On the one hand, the senior generation possess the tacit knowledge on new venture creation whilst the younger generation brings new ideas from their unique unbringings (Magrelli et al., 2022). Secondly, the senior generation is able to offer support especially from their experience, longer histories, connections that assist the younger generation, who take leadership roles in entrepreneurial projects. Thirdly, the established patterns of communication in the family system generate efficiency for disseminating information and legitimacy, enhancing entrepreneurial venturing. Therefore, we propose:

Proposition 6.

A family firm's schema with a combination of older and younger family members will enhance the EE’s schema.

Moreover, individual senior generation family members' interactions with other EE actors pose advantages and disadvantages. Specifically, senior family members may use their enhanced position in the EE to identify and support other young nonfamily entrepreneurs. They may be motivated by reciprocity, especially if they feel indebted to the EE, which has helped them build and sustain their firms, as a form of citizenship behavior (Perkins et al., 2002). This motivation may be stronger in family firms lacking next generation members as a form of phantom succession. In such a circumstance, the senior generation family members may seek continuity of their legacy through a nonfamily member from the EE, ensuring continuity of cohesion, i.e. shared entrepreneurial values. This citizenship behavior is demonstrated by providing coaching, emotional support, resources, introducing contacts and positive references. Senior generation family members may refer to this benefactor as their “prodigy” or “non-family successor” and exhibit a peculiar form of altruism, a common characteristic in family firms (Schulze et al., 2003). Hence, we propose:

Proposition 7A.

Senior generation family members may enhance the EE by engaging in citizenship behaviors and mentoring younger entrepreneurs in the EE.

Alternatively, senior generation family members may perceive younger nonfamily entrepreneurs as a threat to their family firm. New ventures may disrupt the existing practices and “status quo” that the family firm's competencies are based on. A senior generation family member, with their enhanced position in the network (due to their long-standing investment in the EE) may diffuse this threat by several possible behaviors. For example, they may de-legitimize the entrepreneur's ideas, resulting in a lack of legitimacy by the EE. Alternatively, they may withhold information and contacts that may help the young entrepreneur in starting their new venture. Thus, we also propose:

Proposition 7B.

Senior generation family members may use their position in the EE to constrain and delegitimize new ventures that threaten their firm’s existing activities.

In regard to the next generation family members, they have potential synergies with both young and old actors of the EE. Next generation family members are more likely to align with other actors in the EE of a similar age in terms of values, experience, language and motivations, due to the fact they are from the same generational cohort (Magrelli et al., 2022). In addition, next generation family members are motivated to prove themselves (especially to the senior generation family members) and seek to rejuvenate their family firm's schema by creating new ventures. In addition, some family firms may experience unexpected life events such as death or illness that unexpectedly remove the senior generation from the firm (Carr et al., 2011), which may leave a void in the younger generation's life. This void may be filled by senior entrepreneurs from the EE who may feel obliged, out of a respect for the deceased family member, resulting in citizenship behaviors (Perkins et al., 2002). Older long-standing nonfamily entrepreneurs maybe attracted to the next generation family members due to their enhanced position in the family structure (Pearson et al., 2008), providing access to tacit knowledge, information and contacts, all of which are needed in new ventures. This combination between nonfamily entrepreneurs and family members results in a synergy producing EE outputs, i.e. new ventures and productive entrepreneurship. Therefore, we propose:

Proposition 8.

Next generation family members bring benefits from their access to the family firm's schema that when combined with nonfamily entrepreneurs strengthen the likelihood of successful new ventures, enhancing the EE

In conclusion, our theorization through social capital theory shows how the family’s schema, next generation family members and senior generation family members enhance or constrain productive entrepreneurship. However, it may also lead to counterproductive entrepreneurship through the abuse of their position within the EE. Our 10 theoretical propositions build on our original model and culminate in Figure 2.

5. Conclusions

5.1 Discussion and contributions

Despite the increasing attention received, EEs and family firms were mostly studied in isolation. This research through propositional theorizing set out to address this gap by examining how EEs influence family firms and by extension, how family firms influence EEs they are located in. To achieve this, we posed the following research question: “How does social capital theory explain the interactions, and their positive and/or negative effects, between family firms and entrepreneurial ecosystems?” To answer this research question, we examined the social interactions between family firms and the EE on three levels: the macro, the meso and the micro. Particularly, we based our theory on the notion of each social arena possessing a particular schema, which is manifest in the structure that manifests its own characteristics (norms, expectations and historical interactions) that influence current and future behaviors. In doing so, we contribute a fine-grained explanation of the interactions between family firms and their EE. Thereby, generating several propositions and future research directions, summarized in Table 3. Ultimately, through our propositional theorizing we make contributions to the family firm and EE literatures.

For the family firm literature, we make a theoretical contribution by furthering our understanding of external family social capital (Hadjielias et al., 2022; Arregle et al., 2007). This compliments prior work that has focused on internal family social capital (Pearson et al., 2008; Sanchez-Ruiz et al., 2019) and broadens our understanding of the positive and negative impact a family firm has on its environment (Stasa and Machek, 2022). Secondly, in synthesizing the EE literature, our research creates a conceptual shift to include family firms as potentially key actors in the EE and consequently productive entrepreneurship. This brings a novel perspective as the interaction between the two phenomena has only been implicitly touched upon in instances of regional “Familiness” (Basco, 2015, 2024) and positive environmental impact (Baù et al., 2019). Secondly, we answer calls from Magrelli et al. (2022) to consider the older and younger members of the family firm in different contexts, here we have utilized the EE context. We considered what effects family members, from both the junior and senior generation, are likely to have on the EE, specifically elucidating the important role of the family’s schema.

Finally, by examining the interplay between family firms and EEs also responds to the recent calls to calls from the EE literature for diversity in entrepreneurship research and the need to study diverse ecosystem actors beyond high-growth/high-tech firms (Welter et al., 2017; Neumeyer et al., 2019; Spigel et al., 2020; Wurth et al., 2022). Through its propositions, this study contributes to the ongoing attempts for examining heterogeneity within and across EEs (Scheidgen, 2020; Spigel, 2022; Schrijvers et al., 2024).

5.2 Implications for practitioners and policy makers

Through the application of an established theoretical lens, social capital, the 10 novel propositions provide insights for EE practitioners and policy makers to better understand the potential unique impact family firms have on EE and therefore productive entrepreneurship.

Policy makers benefit from this research because it identifies specific behaviors they should seek to support. Specifically, senior generation family members, specifically those who do not have a next generation member entering the firm, may be motivated by reciprocity and altruism to support and coach next generation entrepreneurs. This is a huge untapped resource for the EE and could help generate productive entrepreneurship and enhance the EE’s diversity and by extension its resilience (Roundy et al., 2017). Thus, policies can incentivize and structure coaching schemes facilitating senior entrepreneurs and younger entrepreneurs to interact and build relationships. This could be facilitated by the EE's anchor institutions such as universities and city councils. In current times, social capital can be used as a rationale for lower public spending (Perkins et al., 2002) as it is perceived to be an apparent solution to social problems. However, policymakers must be mindful that social capital is not a substitute for economic resources. Policymakers should then focus on developing and implementing policies that can enable family firms to fulfill their potential contribution to the EE in terms of productive entrepreneurship and resilience.

5.3 Future research directions

Reflections upon the existing literature from both streams of research has resulted in 10 robust theoretical propositions and simultaneously uncovered research gaps. In this section, we articulate “what we do not yet explicitly know” at the intersection of these two literatures on three levels of analysis (macro, meso, micro). We propose that the identified research gaps are the focus of future contributions to advance the current theorization and further synthesize the two domains.

5.3.1 Macro level

The entrepreneurship and EE literature established a need to identify more actors that influence socio-economic development (Welter et al., 2017; Wurth et al., 2022). From a theoretical perspective, we have reflected on the potential benefits social capital in the EE brings to entrepreneurs and new ventures (Proposition 1). However, this proposition is grounded in the structural perspective of social capital, one that emphasizes the importance of structure, underestimating the essence of social capital. There are two important but unexplored factors here. Firstly, the essence of social capital takes time to form hence the presence of a degree of closure and sustained interaction that comprise durable and lasting relations (Bourdieu, 1987). A gap emerges pertaining to how long this will take to reach a sufficient level to become instrumental for the EE actors. Secondly, social capital is the value individuals appropriate from the structures (Sandefer and Laurman, 1998). This process of appropriation requires investment of time and energy to sustain relationships (Adler and Kwon, 2002). Knowing the minimum threshold would help EE actors understand how much they need to invest in EEs before expecting any return. Therefore, it would be interesting to explore how long an entrepreneur is required to participate in EE before being able to appropriate benefits (RQ1).

Furthermore, while our theorization led us to consider both the benefits of social capital (legitimacy and informational advantages) and also the drawbacks that lead to counterproductive entrepreneurship, it remains to be seen how these behaviors occur in practice. This can be explored by observing EE and understanding which behavior delegitimize new opportunities and what behaviors result in constraining behaviors (RQ2). This would help uncover how the dark side of social capital may have a negative impact on EE's productive entrepreneurship and resilience, advancing literature by providing a more complete understanding of EE.

5.3.2 Meso level

Importantly, through our theoretical reasoning we acknowledge the potential limitations of social capital due to the cost of maintenance. However, what remains unclear is the specific behaviors, i.e. antecedents that build social capital as well as whether these behaviors are always effective through the different stages of the life cycle. It may be that the continuous patterned interaction, which leads to lasting and durable relationships that provide benefits (Granovetter, 1995), is only beneficial at certain points i.e. in the case of new ventures access to different information from different people is required in different moments. For example, the interaction in a diverse network leading to information advantages is more relevant at the initial stages of the new venture's life cycle because it supplies a form of non-redundant information (Burt, 1992). Whereas, in subsequent phases the founding teams with strong forms of relational capital manifest a more content oriented form of social capital and thus is more valuable at this stage. Consequently, it would be interesting to know at which stage of a new venture accessing the EE social capital is most effective and whether this diminishes or increases across the different phases of the new venture's life cycle (RQ3).

Family firms are known to become risk averse (Kotlar et al., 2020), stick to the status quo (Cassia et al., 2012) and their traditions (De Massis et al., 2016). All of which are likely to contribute to counterproductive behaviors in the EE and consequently contribute to counterproductive entrepreneurship. From this line of reasoning, it would be interesting to observe how long-standing family firms interact with the EE and if there are examples that contradict this logic. In both cases, future research should longitudinally observe the interaction between long-standing firms and their EE (RQ4). This will advance knowledge by explicating a specific form of actor in the EE and their contribution to either productive or counterproductive entrepreneurship.

5.3.3 Micro level

Generally, research focusing on the specific actors is required to advance this line of research. Literature acknowledges that the family firm's schema is influenced by the individual members of the family firm (Habbershon et al., 2003). Thus, to further the research of the EE, it would be interesting to explicitly observe how next generation family members utilize their access to the family system and family resources (that separates them from nonfamily members), in the context of EE (RQ5).

Furthermore, our reasoning outlined how a family's schema formed by a concentration of senior generation family members, also known as a stagnant organization (Ward, 1986), is likely to have a negative impact on the EE. Therefore, it would be interesting to identify what behaviors senior generations' family members exhibit when interacting with the EE who are part of a stagnant organization, as well as their attitudes, behaviors and feelings towards upcoming changes in the EE (RQ6). This could help identify situations in which the EE is stagnant, and this is especially poignant in an aging population and ones which specifically have a high proportion of family firms, such as Italy (Cascino et al., 2010).

Our theoretical reasoning also explicated how the family's schema is influenced by both junior and senior family business members. Having a mixture ensures cognitive diversity and thus contributes more to the EE outputs and resilience (Roundy et al., 2017). However, what is underexplained is how the advantages of internal family social capital through intergenerational relations (Magrelli et al., 2022) can contribute to the EE and more precisely the nature of such interactions and specific related behaviors (RQ7). In identifying the peculiar behavior of multi-generational family members that benefit EE, it can extend and refine the current list of attributes that are required for functioning EEs.

The family firm literature is anticipating the succession crisis, a state in which the next generation members are either non-existent or not entering the firm (Garcia et al., 2019). This results in an abundance of senior generation family members and not enough junior family business members, which may not only hinder but also benefit the EE. Future research can broaden our understanding of these situations. Firstly, future research can focus on senior generation family members, particularly those who do not have the next generation coming into the firm and observe their interactions with entrepreneurs in the EE. This can inform whether and how they perform mentoring roles and whether their reciprocity and altruism that builds the typical family's schema and whether this extends to the EE’s schema (RQ8). Identifying such empirical examples of such behaviors would inform more beneficial aspects that family firms bring to the EE.

On the other hand, since family firms seek transgenerational wealth transfer (Habbershon et al., 2003) and they seek to protect their SEW that sometimes skews their economic rationality (Kotlar et al., 2020). Our reasoning proposes that they may use their esteemed position, as successful business owners in the EE, to constrain younger upcoming entrepreneurs in a bid to protect their status quo and their firms existing competences, which may be destroyed in the wake of new products and services that supersede them (Schumpeter, 1934; Morck and Yeung, 2003). Therefore, capturing these behaviors such as attempts to delegitimize and withhold information from entrepreneurs, can help capture counterproductive behaviors and advance theory on EE (RQ9).

Furthermore, the dynamic nature of EE (Brown and Mason, 2017) aligns with the idea of generational change in family firms (Magrelli et al., 2022). Thereby, our logic has considered situations in which the next generation accesses the family system to boost their entrepreneurial efforts. Furthermore, in situations next generation family members may link up with both young nonfamily entrepreneurs and even older nonfamily entrepreneurs. In both cases, it would be interesting to observe what specific unique resources, derived from enhanced family social capital, a family member brings to new ventures (RQ10). This would help explain the unique positive impact a family firm has on EE and therefore productive entrepreneurship. Table 3 summarizes the future research directions.

5.4 Final note

This research set out to bridge the gap between two important research domains to entrepreneurship: family firms and EEs. We established social capital as a common theoretical ground to develop 10 unique propositions that explain how family firms influence the functionality of EE, as well how the EE itself may influence the operations and interactions of family firms. In addition, we identify future research questions to guide scholars in advancing this novel but increasingly relevant phenomenon. In doing so, we contribute to EE, family firm and social capital literatures.

Figures

The entrepreneurial ecosystems’ social elements across micro, meso, macro levels pre-theorization

Figure 1

The entrepreneurial ecosystems’ social elements across micro, meso, macro levels pre-theorization

The entrepreneurial ecosystems’ social elements across micro, meso, macro levels post-theorization

Figure 2

The entrepreneurial ecosystems’ social elements across micro, meso, macro levels post-theorization

Attempted systematic review process

Figure A1

Attempted systematic review process

Expansive/specified versus narrow/vague definitions of entrepreneurial ecosystems

Author(s)DefinitionAuthors' analysis of definition
Mason and Brown (2013, p. 5)“[A] set of interconnected entrepreneurial actors (both potential and existing), entrepreneurial organizations (e. g. firms, venture capitalists, business angels, banks), institutions (universities, public sector agencies, financial bodies), and entrepreneurial processes (e. g. the business birth rate, numbers of high growth firms, levels of “blockbuster entrepreneurship”, number of serial entrepreneurs, degree of sellout mentality within firms, and levels of entrepreneurial ambition), which formally and informally coalesce to connect, mediate and govern the performance within the local entrepreneurial environment”Expansive and specific
Spigel (2017, p. 50)“A combination of social, political, economic, and cultural elements within a region that support the development and growth of innovative start-ups and encourage nascent entrepreneurs and other actors to take the risks of starting, funding, and otherwise assisting high-risk ventures”Expansive and all encompassing
Ács et al., (2014, p. 479)“A dynamic, institutionally embedded interaction between entrepreneurial attitudes, abilities, and aspirations, by individuals which drives the allocation of resources through the creation and operation of new ventures”Entrepreneur focussed
Stam (2015, p. 1765)“A set of interdependent actors and factors coordinated in such a way that they enable productive entrepreneurship”Inclusive, narrow focus on productive entrepreneurship
Bruns et al. (2017, p. 1)“Entrepreneurial ecosystem as a multidimensional set of interacting factors that moderate the effect of entrepreneurial activity on economic growth”All encompassing
van Rijnsoever (2020, p. 2)“A set of actors that interact and exchange resources in a network under an institutional regime and an infrastructure”Narrow focus on institutional aspects

Source(s): Adapted from Rocha et al. (2021, p. 3) created by authors

Constructs used in the propositional theorizing process

ConstructDescriptionLevel of analysisSources
Junior family membersMembers of the family with a member from the preceding generation still active in the firmMicroArregle et al. (2007), Pearson et al. (2008)
Senior family membersMembers of the family with a member of the next generation active in the firmMicroArregle et al. (2007), Pearson et al. (2008)
Family firmsA firm owned by (two or more) members of the same family, who are involved in the firm, either via management or governanceMesoChua et al. (1999)
Family firm schemaThe family’s set of values, sanctions, norms, expectations, unspoken rules, and tacit knowledge that influence subsequent behavior of the family members inside and outside the boundaries of the firmMesoLong (2011), Lester and Canella (2006), Sorenson et al. (2009)
Productive entrepreneurshipEntrepreneurial activity that generates a positive socio-economic impactMacroBaumol (1993)
Regional social networksProvide resources for actors, such as access to valuable information in a timely mannerMesoSpigel (2017)
EE ResilienceDepends on the interplay between ecosystem diversity and coherence. Demonstrates the degree to which an EE can recover from internal and external shocksMacroHacklr and Mayer (2008), Eraydin et al. (2010), Roundy et al. (2017), Spigel and Harrison (2018)
EE LegitimacyThe degree to which the activities of an EE entity are proper, desirable, or appropriate in relation to the EE schemaMicroSuchman (1995), Zimmerman and Zeitz (2002)
EE schemaThe EE's set of values, norms, expectations, unspoken rules, and obligations that influence EE interactionsMacroWurth et al. (2022)

Source(s): Created by authors

Propositions and future research directions

Level of analysisPropositions generated from social capital theoryUnanswered research questions
Macro-MicroProposition 1A: The longer and more coherent an entrepreneur is with the EE’s schema the greater their access to resources from the EEHow long is required for an entrepreneur to participate in the EE's schema before they can appropriate the benefits associated with social capital?
Proposition 1B: The longer and more coherent an entrepreneur is with the EE ‘schema’ the more legitimacy is assigned to their new venturesHow do constraining behaviors manifest in EE? What behaviors can be associated with legitimizing and constraining behaviors?
Macro-Meso levelProposition 2: An entrepreneur must be careful of the diminishing returns of social capital from the EE and the potential distractions of EE networkingDoes EE social capital have greater (or lesser) advantages at different stages of the new venture creation process?
Proposition 3: A long-standing family firm in an EE can use their position to de-legitimize opportunities that they perceive as riskyHow do long-standing firms interact in the EE? Do they bring any unique benefits or hindrances to the EE?
Meso-micro levelProposition 4: Next generation family members can utilise the family firm’s schema as well as the EE's schema to increase the legitimacy and attraction of their new ventures to potential partnersHow do family entrepreneurs appropriate resources from the family system for utilization in the EE that lead to productive entrepreneurship?
Proposition 5: When senior generation family members form a family firm's schema it becomes stagnant and lacks diversity required for an EE to create productive entrepreneurshipHow do family members of a stagnant organization interact with the EE? Does this constrain the EE and lead to counterproductive entrepreneurship?
Proposition 6: A family firm's schema with a combination of older and younger family members will enhance the EE’s schema.How do intergenerational family TMTs interact and create synergies with the EE?
Meso-micro levelProposition 7A: Senior generation family members may enhance the EE by engaging in citizenship behaviors and mentoring younger entrepreneurs in the EEWhat roles do senior generation family members play in EE? Do they exhibit any supporting behaviors for other entrepreneurs?
Proposition 7B: Senior generation family members may use their position in the EE to constrain and delegitimize new ventures that threaten their own firms existing activitiesDo senior generation family members display negative behaviors, attitudes or feelings towards younger entrepreneurs in the EE?
Proposition 8: Next generation family members bring benefits from their access to the family schema that when combined with nonfamily entrepreneurs strengthen the likelihood of successful new ventures, enhancing the EEWhat relationships do junior generation family members form in the EE? Do they leverage their access to the family firm system for new ventures?

Source(s): Created by authors

Rationale for excluding scientific articles from the literature review process

Reason for exclusionsExplanation
Not related to family firms (n = 17)These articles, mostly, contained some element of family factors, such as family upbringing in relation to entrepreneurial behaviors. While these are interesting for entrepreneurship scholars, they fall out of the scope of the aim of this article
Not related to entrepreneurial ecosystems (n = 9)These articles, while analyzing some aspect of family firms in relation to the environment, were not referring to the EE or engaging with the literature on EEs
Not related to family firms or entrepreneurial ecosystems (n = 14)Not relevant to either family firms or EEs
Not peer reviewed (n = 6)Not of sufficient quality to qualify as contributions to knowledge

Notes

1.

We would also like to note that theory building via a systematic literature review (Breslin and Gatrell, 2023) was not viable due to the identification of five articles that sufficiently analyze family firms and EE, following the traditional systematic literature review process (Transfield et al., 2003), and more details of this can be found in Appendix 1.

Appendix 1 Search results of attempted systematic literature review of family firms and EEs

Table A1Figure A1

Appendix 2

Table A2

References

Ács, Z.J., Autio, E. and Szerb, L. (2014), “National systems of entrepreneurship: measurement issues and policy implications”, Research Policy, Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 476-494, doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.016.

Adler, P.S. and Kwon, S.-W. (2002), “Social capital: prospects for a new concept”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 27 No. 1, pp. 17-39, doi: 10.2307/4134367.

Arregle, J.-L., Hitt, M.A., Sirmon, D.G. and Very, P. (2007), “The development of organizational social capital: attributes of family firms”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 44 No. 1, pp. 73-95, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2007.00665.x.

Bacharach, S.B. (1989), “Organizational theories: some criteria for evaluation”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 14 No. 4, pp. 496-515, doi: 10.5465/amr.1989.4308374.

Banfield, E. (1958), The Moral Basis of a Backward Society, Free Press, New York.

Basco, R. (2015), “Family business and regional development—a theoretical model of regional familiness”, Journal of Family Business Strategy, Vol. 6 No. 4, pp. 259-271, doi: 10.1016/j.jfbs.2015.04.004.

Basco, R. (2024), “Regional development and family business: a perspective article”, Journal of Family Business Management, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print, doi: 10.1108/JFBM-11-2023-0285.

Baù, M., Chirico, F., Pittino, D., Backman, M. and Klaesson, J. (2019), “Roots to grow: family firms and local embeddedness in rural and urban contexts”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 360-385, doi: 10.1177/1042258718796089.

Baumol, W.J. (1993), Entrepreneurship, Management, and the Structure of Payoffs, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Benavides-Salazar, C., Iturrioz-Landart, C., Aragón-Amonarriz, C. and Ibañez-Romero, A. (2022), “The role of entrepreneurial families in entrepreneurial ecosystems: the family social capital approach”, Journal of Entrepreneurship in Emerging Economies, Vol. 14 No. 6, pp. 1001-1032, doi: 10.1108/jeee-11-2020-0416.

Bergman, B.J. and McMullen, J.S. (2022), “Helping entrepreneurs help themselves: a review and relational research agenda on entrepreneurial support organizations”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 46 No. 3, pp. 688-728, doi: 10.1177/10422587211028736.

Bhawe, N. and Zahra, S.A. (2019), “Inducing heterogeneity in local entrepreneurial ecosystems: the role of MNEs”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 52 No. 2, pp. 437-454, doi: 10.1007/s11187-017-9954-7.

Bichler, B.F., Kallmuenzer, A., Peters, M., Petry, T. and Clauss, T. (2022), “Regional entrepreneurial ecosystems: how family firm embeddedness triggers ecosystem development”, Review of Managerial Science, Vol. 16 No. 1, pp. 15-44, doi: 10.1007/s11846-020-00434-9.

Bourdieu, P. (1987), “The forms of capital”, in The Sociology of Economic Life, Routledge, pp. 78-92.

Breslin, D. and Gatrell, C. (2023), “Theorizing through literature reviews: the miner-prospector continuum”, Organizational Research Methods, Vol. 26 No. 1, pp. 139-167, doi: 10.1177/1094428120943288.

Brown, R. and Mason, C. (2017), “Looking inside the spiky bits: a critical review and conceptualisation of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 11-30, doi: 10.1007/s11187-017-9865-7.

Bruns, K., Bosma, N., Sanders, M. and Schramm, M. (2017), “Searching for the existence of entrepreneurial ecosystems: a regional cross-section growth regression approach”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 31-54.

Burt, R.S. (1992), Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition, Harvard University Press, London.

Burt, R.S. (1997), “A note on social capital and network content”, Social Networks, Vol. 19 No. 4, pp. 355-373, doi: 10.1016/s0378-8733(97)00003-8.

Burt, R.S. (2002), “The social capital of structural holes”, The New Economic Sociology: Developments in an Emerging Field, Vol. 148 No. 90, p. 122.

Burt, R.S. and Opper, S. (2020), “Political connection and disconnection: still a success factor for Chinese entrepreneurs”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 44 No. 6, pp. 1199-1228.

Campopiano, G. and De Massis, A. (2015), “Corporate social responsibility reporting: a content analysis in family and non-family firms”, Journal of Business Ethics, Vol. 129 No. 3, pp. 511-534, doi: 10.1007/s10551-014-2174-z.

Carr, J.C., Cole, M.S., Ring, J.K. and Blettner, D.P. (2011), “A measure of variations in internal social capital among family firms”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 35 No. 6, pp. 1207-1227, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2011.00499.x.

Cascino, S., Pugliese, A., Mussolino, D. and Sansone, C. (2010), “The influence of family ownership on the quality of accounting information”, Family Business Review, Vol. 23 No. 3, pp. 246-265, doi: 10.1177/0894486510374302.

Cassia, L., De Massis, A. and Pizzurno, E. (2012), “Strategic innovation and new product development in family firms: an empirically grounded theoretical framework”, International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior and Research, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 198-232, doi: 10.1108/13552551211204229.

Chirico, F., Sirmon, D.G., Sciascia, S. and Mazzola, P. (2011), “Resource orchestration in family firms: investigating how entrepreneurial orientation, generational involvement, and participative strategy affect performance”, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Vol. 5 No. 4, pp. 307-326, doi: 10.1002/sej.121.

Chua, J., Chrisman, J. and Sharma, P. (1999), “Defining the family business by behavior”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 23 No. 4, pp. 19-39.

Cobben, D., Neessen, P.C.M., Rus, D. and Roijakkers, N. (2023), “How family firms use governance mechanisms to mitigate the risks of ecosystems: a case study from healthcare”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 60 No. 4, pp. 1369-1388, doi: 10.1007/s11187-022-00667-w.

Cohen, A. and Sharma, P. (2016), Entrepreneurs in Every Generation: How Successful Family Businesses Develop Their Next Leaders, Berrett-Koehler, Oakland, California.

Coleman, J.S. (1988), “Social capital in the creation of human capital”, American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 94, pp. 95-120, doi: 10.1086/228943.

Colquitt, J.A. and Zapata-Phelan, C.P. (2007), “Trends in theory building and theory testing: a five-decade study of the ‘Academy of Management Journal’”, The Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 50 No. 6, pp. 1281-1303, doi: 10.5465/amj.2007.28165855. available at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/20159472.

Cornelissen, J. (2017), “Editor's comments: developing propositions, a process model, or a typology? Addressing the challenges of writing theory without a boilerplate”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 42 No. 1, pp. 1-9, doi: 10.5465/amr.2016.0196, available at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/24906272.

Cornelissen, J., Höllerer, M.A. and Seidl, D. (2021), “What theory is and can be: forms of theorizing in organizational scholarship”, Organization Theory, Vol. 2 No. 3, pp. 1-19, doi: 10.1177/26317877211020328.

Daniel, L.J., De Villiers Scheepers, M.J., Miles, M.P. and De Klerk, S. (2022), “Understanding entrepreneurial ecosystems using complex adaptive systems theory: getting the big picture for economic development, practice, and policy”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 34 Nos 9-10, pp. 911-934, doi: 10.1080/08985626.2022.2083691.

Davis, J.H., Allen, M.R. and Hayes, H.D. (2010), “Is blood thicker than water? A study of stewardship perceptions in family business”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 34 No. 6, pp. 1093-1116, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2010.00415.x.

De Massis, A., Sharma, P., Chua, J.H. and Chrisman, J.J. (2012), Family Business Studies: An Annotated Bibliography, Edward Elgar Publishing, Massachusetts.

De Massis, A., Kotlar, J., Chua, J.H. and Chrisman, J.J. (2014), “Ability and willingness as sufficiency conditions for family-oriented particularistic behavior: implications for theory and empirical studies”, Journal of Small Business Management, Vol. 52 No. 2, pp. 344-364, doi: 10.1111/jsbm.12102.

De Massis, A., Frattini, F., Kotlar, J., Petruzzelli, A.M. and Wright, M. (2016), “Innovation through tradition: lessons from innovative family businesses and directions for future research”, Academy of Management Perspectives, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 93-116, doi: 10.5465/amp.2015.0017.

De Massis, A., Kotlar, J. and Manelli, L. (2021), “Family firms, family boundary organizations, and the family-related organizational ecosystem”, Family Business Review, Vol. 34 No. 4, pp. 350-364, doi: 10.1177/08944865211052195.

Discua Cruz, A., Howorth, C. and Hamilton, E. (2013), “Intrafamily entrepreneurship: the Formation and membership of family entrepreneurial teams”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 17-46, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2012.00534.x.

Eraydin, A., Tasan-Kok, T. and Vranken, J. (2010), “Diversity matters: immigrant entrepreneurship and contribution of different forms of social integration in economic performance of cities”, European Planning Studies, Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 521-543, doi: 10.1080/09654311003593556.

Feld, B. (2012), Startup Communities: Building an Entrepreneurial Ecosystem in Your City, John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, NJ.

Fisher, G., Kotha, S. and Lahiri, A. (2016), “Changing with the times: an integrated view of identity, legitimacy, and new venture life cycles”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 41 No. 3, pp. 383-409, doi: 10.5465/amr.2013.0496.

Fotopoulos, G. (2023), “Knowledge spillovers, entrepreneurial ecosystems and the geography of high growth firms”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 47 No. 5, pp. 1877-1914, doi: 10.1177/10422587221111732.

Garcia, P.R.J.M., Sharma, P., De Massis, A., Wright, M. and Scholes, L. (2019), “Perceived parental behaviors and next-generation engagement in family firms: a social cognitive perspective”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 43 No. 2, pp. 224-243, doi: 10.1177/1042258718796087.

Gedajlovic, E., Honig, B., Moore, C.B., Payne, G.T. and Wright, M. (2013), “Social capital and entrepreneurship: a schema and research agenda”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 455-478, doi: 10.1111/etap.12042.

Gomez-Mejia, L.R., Nuñez-Nickel, M. and Gutierrez, I. (2001), “The role of family ties in agency contracts”, Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 44 No. 1, pp. 81-95, doi: 10.5465/3069338.

Gómez-Mejía, L.R., Haynes, K.T., Núñez-Nickel, M., Jacobson, K.J.L. and Moyano-Fuentes, J. (2007), “Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family-controlled firms: evidence from Spanish olive oil mills”, Administrative Science Quarterly, Vol. 52 No. 1, pp. 106-137, doi: 10.2189/asqu.52.1.106.

Granovetter, M. (1995), “Coase revisited: business groups in the modern economy”, Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 93-130, doi: 10.1093/icc/4.1.93.

Habbershon, T.G. and Williams, M.L. (1999), “A resource-based framework for assessing the strategic advantages of family firms”, Family Business Review, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 1-25, doi: 10.1111/j.1741-6248.1999.00001.x.

Habbershon, T.G., Williams, M. and MacMillan, I.C. (2003), “A unified systems perspective of family firm performance”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 451-465, doi: 10.1016/s0883-9026(03)00053-3.

Hackler, D. and Mayer, H. (2008), “Diversity, entrepreneurship, and the urban environment”, Journal of Urban Affairs, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 273-307, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9906.2008.00396.x.

Hadjielias, E., Hughes, M. and Scholes, L. (2022), “External crises and family social capital reconfiguration: insights from the European debt crisis and the Covid-19 pandemic”, Family Business Review, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 275-305, doi: 10.1177/08944865221113136.

Holt, D.T., Pearson, A.W., Payne, G.T. and Sharma, P. (2018), “Family business research as a boundary-spanning platform”, Family Business Review, Vol. 31 No. 1, pp. 14-31, doi: 10.1177/0894486518758712.

Hruskova, M., Mason, C. and Herzog, S. (2022), “Mapping entrepreneurship support organisations: an examination of the ‘cluttered landscape’ critique”, Local Economy: The Journal of the Local Economy Policy Unit, Vol. 37 No. 7, pp. 541-563, doi: 10.1177/02690942231173655.

Isenberg, D. (2010), “The big idea: how to start an entrepreneurial revolution”, Harvard Business Review, Vol. 88 No. 6, pp. 40-50.

Khoury, T.A., Junkunc, M. and Deeds, D.L. (2013), “The social construction of legitimacy through signaling social capital: exploring the conditional value of alliances and underwriters at IPO”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 569-601, doi: 10.1111/etap.12030.

Klein, K.J., Tosi, H. and AlbertCannella, A.J. (1999), “Multilevel theory building: benefits, barriers, and new developments”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 24 No. 2, pp. 248-253, doi: 10.5465/amr.1999.1893934.

Kotlar, J., De Massis, A., Frattini, F. and Kammerlander, N. (2020), “Motivation gaps and implementation traps: the paradoxical and time-varying effects of family ownership on firm absorptive capacity”, Journal of Product Innovation Management, Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 2-25, doi: 10.1111/jpim.12503.

Kreiser, P.M., Patel, P.C. and Fiet, J.O. (2013), “The influence of changes in social capital on firm–founding activities”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 539-567, doi: 10.1111/etap.12039.

Lasrado, V., Sivo, S., Ford, C., O'Neal, T. and Garibay, I. (2016), “Do graduated university incubator firms benefit from their relationship with university incubators?”, The Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 41 No. 2, pp. 205-219, doi: 10.1007/s10961-015-9412-0.

Lester, R.H. and Cannella, A.A. (2006), “Interorganizational familiness: how family firms use interlocking directorates to build community–level social capital”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 30 No. 6, pp. 755-775, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2006.00149.x.

Long, R.G. (2011), “Commentary: social exchange in building, modeling, and managing family social capital”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 35 No. 6, pp. 1229-1234, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2011.00500.x.

Long, R. and Mathews, K. (2011), “Ethics in the family firm: cohesion through reciprocity and exchange”, Business Ethics Quarterly, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 287-308, doi: 10.5840/beq201121217.

Lumpkin, G.T., Brigham, K.H. and Moss, T.W. (2010), “Long-term orientation: implications for the entrepreneurial orientation and performance of family businesses”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 22 Nos 3-4, pp. 241-264, doi: 10.1080/08985621003726218.

Madison, K., Holt, D.T., Kellermanns, F.W. and Ranft, A.L. (2016), “Viewing family firm behavior and governance through the lens of agency and stewardship theories”, Family Business Review, Vol. 29 No. 1, pp. 65-93, doi: 10.1177/0894486515594292.

Magrelli, V., Rovelli, P., Benedetti, C., Überbacher, R. and De Massis, A. (2022), “Generations in family business: a multifield review and future research agenda”, Family Business Review, Vol. 35 No. 1, pp. 15-44, doi: 10.1177/08944865211069781.

Malecki, E.J. (2018), “Entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Geography Compass, Vol. 12 No. 3, 12359, doi: 10.1111/gec3.12359.

Mason, C. and Brown, R. (2013), “Entrepreneurial ecosystems and growth oriented entrepreneurship”, Final Report to the OECD, Vol. 30 No. 1, pp. 77-102.

Memili, E., Fang, H., Chrisman, J.J. and De Massis, A. (2015), “The impact of small- and medium-sized family firms on economic growth”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 45 No. 4, pp. 771-785, doi: 10.1007/s11187-015-9670-0.

Molly, V., Laveren, E. and Jorissen, A. (2012), “Intergenerational differences in family firms: impact on capital structure and growth behavior”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 36 No. 4, pp. 703-725, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2010.00429.x.

Moran, P. (2005), “Structural vs. relational embeddedness: social capital and managerial performance”, Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 26 No. 12, pp. 1129-1151, doi: 10.1002/smj.486.

Morck, R. and Yeung, B. (2003), “Agency problems in large family business groups”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 27 No. 4, pp. 367-382.

Nahapiet, J. and Ghoshal, S. (1998), “Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 23 No. 2, pp. 242-266, doi: 10.5465/amr.1998.533225.

Neumeyer, X., Santos, S.C. and Morris, M.H. (2019), “Who is left out: exploring social boundaries in entrepreneurial ecosystems”, The Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 462-484, doi: 10.1007/s10961-018-9694-0.

Packalen, K.A. (2007), “Complementing capital: the role of status, demographic features, and social capital in founding teams' abilities to obtain resources”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 31 No. 6, pp. 873-891, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2007.00210.x.

Payne, G.T., Moore, C.B., Griffis, S.E. and Autry, C.W. (2011), Multilevel challenges and opportunities in social capital research, in Aguinis, H., Boyd, B.K., Pierce, C.A. and Short, J.C. (Eds.), Journal of Management, Vol. 37 No. 2, pp. 491-520.

Pearson, A.W., Carr, J.C. and Shaw, J.C. (2008), “Toward a theory of familiness: a social capital perspective”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 32 No. 6, pp. 949-969, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2008.00265.x.

Perkins, D.D., Hughey, J. and Speer, P.W. (2002), “Community psychology perspectives on social capital theory and community development practice”, Community Development Society, Vol. 33 No. 1, pp. 33-52, doi: 10.1080/15575330209490141.

Pollack, J.M., Rutherford, M.W. and Nagy, B.G. (2012), “Preparedness and cognitive legitimacy as antecedents of new venture funding in televised business pitches”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 36 No. 5, pp. 915-939, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2012.00531.x.

Portes, A. (1998), “Social capital: its origins and applications in modern sociology”, Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 24 No. 1, pp. 1-24, doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.24.1.1.

Pugh, R., Soetanto, D., Jack, S.L. and Hamilton, E. (2019), “Developing local entrepreneurial ecosystems through integrated learning initiatives: the Lancaster case”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 56 No. 2, pp. 833-847, doi: 10.1007/s11187-019-00271-5.

Ratten, V. (2020), “Entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Thunderbird International Business Review, Vol. 62 No. 5, pp. 447-455, doi: 10.1002/tie.22164.

Rocha, A., Brown, R. and Mawson, S. (2021), “Capturing conversations in entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Research Policy, Vol. 50 No. 9, 104317.

Röd, I. (2016), “Disentangling the family firm's innovation process: a systematic review”, Journal of Family Business Strategy, Vol. 7 No. 3, pp. 185-201, doi: 10.1016/j.jfbs.2016.08.004.

Roundy, P.T. (2017), “Social entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial ecosystems: complementary or disjoint phenomena?”, International Journal of Social Economics, Vol. 44 No. 9, pp. 1252-1267, doi: 10.1108/ijse-02-2016-0045.

Roundy, P.T., Brockman, B.K. and Bradshaw, M. (2017), “The resilience of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Journal of Business Venturing Insights, Vol. 8, pp. 99-104.

Ryan, P., Giblin, M., Buciuni, G. and Kogler, D.F. (2020), “The role of MNEs in the genesis and growth of a resilient entrepreneurial ecosystem”, The Dynamics of Entrepreneurial Ecosystems, Vol. 33 Nos 1-2, pp. 36-53, doi: 10.1080/08985626.2020.1734260.

Sanchez-Ruiz, P., Daspit, J., Holt, D. and Rutherford, M. (2019), “Family social capital in the family firm: a taxonomic classification, relationships with outcomes, and directions for advancement”, Family Business Review, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 131-153.

Sandberg, J. and Alvesson, M. (2010), “Ways of constructing research questions: gap-spotting or problematization?”, Organization, Vol. 18 No. 1, pp. 23-44, doi: 10.1177/1350508410372151.

Sandefur, R.L. and Laumann, E.O. (1998), “A paradigm for social capital”, Rationality and Society, Vol. 10 No. 4, pp. 481-501, doi: 10.1177/104346398010004005.

Scheidgen, K. (2020), “Degrees of integration: how a fragmented entrepreneurial ecosystem promotes different types of entrepreneurs”, The Dynamics of Entrepreneurial Ecosystems, Vol. 33 Nos 1-2, pp. 1-26, doi: 10.1080/08985626.2020.1734263.

Schrijvers, M., Stam, E. and Bosma, N. (2024), “Figuring it out: configurations of high-performing entrepreneurial ecosystems in Europe”, Regional Studies, Vol. 58 No. 5, pp. 1096-1110, doi: 10.1080/00343404.2023.2226727.

Schulze, W.S., Lubatkin, M.H. and Dino, R.N. (2003), “Toward a theory of agency and altruism in family firms”, Journal of Business Venturing, Vol. 18 No. 4, pp. 473-490, doi: 10.1016/s0883-9026(03)00054-5.

Schumpeter (1934), “The theory of economic development”, The European Heritage in Economics and the Social Sciences, Vol. 1, pp. 61-116, doi: 10.1007/0-306-48082-4_3.

Sharma, P. (2008), “Commentary: familiness: capital stocks and flows between family and business”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 32 No. 6, pp. 971-977, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2008.00266.x.

Sharma, P., Chrisman, J.J. and Chua, J.H. (1996), A Review and Annotated Bibliography of Family Business Studies, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Massachusetts.

Siaba, S. and Rivera, B. (2024), “The evolution of the field of family business research over a decade (2012–2022)”, Small Business Economics, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print, doi: 10.1007/s11187-023-00866-z.

Sorenson, R.L., Goodpaster, K.E., Hedberg, P.R. and Yu, A. (2009), “The family point of view, family social capital, and firm performance: an exploratory test”, Family Business Review, Vol. 22 No. 3, pp. 239-253, doi: 10.1177/0894486509332456.

Spigel, B. (2017), “The relational organization of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 41 No. 1, pp. 49-72, doi: 10.1111/etap.12167.

Spigel, B. (2020), Entrepreneurial Ecosystems: Theory, Practice and Futures, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham; Northampton, MA.

Spigel, B. (2022), “Examining the cohesiveness and nestedness entrepreneurial ecosystems: evidence from British FinTechs”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 59 No. 4, pp. 1381-1399, doi: 10.1007/s11187-021-00589-z.

Spigel, B. and Harrison, R. (2018), “Toward a process theory of entrepreneurial ecosystems: toward a process theory of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 151-168, doi: 10.1002/sej.1268.

Spigel, B., Kitagawa, F. and Mason, C. (2020), “A manifesto for researching entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Local Economy: The Journal of the Local Economy Policy Unit, Vol. 35 No. 5, pp. 482-495, doi: 10.1177/0269094220959052.

Stam, E. (2015), “Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique”, European Planning Studies, Vol. 23 No. 9, pp. 1759-1769, doi: 10.1080/09654313.2015.1061484.

Stasa, M. and Machek, O. (2022), “Social capital in the family business literature: a systematic review and future research agenda”, Family Business Review, Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 415-441, doi: 10.1177/08944865221125520.

Suchman, M.C. (1995), “Managing legitimacy: strategic and institutional approaches”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 20 No. 3, p. 571, doi: 10.2307/258788.

Suddaby, R. (2010), “Editor's comments: construct clarity in theories of management and organization”, The Academy of Management Review, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 346-357, doi: 10.5465/amr.2010.51141319, available at: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25682418.

Theodoraki, C., Messeghem, K. and Rice, M.P. (2018), “A social capital approach to the development of sustainable entrepreneurial ecosystems: an explorative study”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 51 No. 1, pp. 153-170, doi: 10.1007/s11187-017-9924-0.

Thompson, T.A., Purdy, J.M. and Ventresca, M.J. (2018), “How entrepreneurial ecosystems take form: evidence from social impact initiatives in Seattle”, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 96-116, doi: 10.1002/sej.1285.

Tranfield, D., Denyer, D. and Smart, P. (2003), “Towards a methodology for developing evidence-informed management knowledge by means of systematic review”, British Journal of Management, Vol. 14 No. 3, pp. 207-222, doi: 10.1111/1467-8551.00375.

van Rijnsoever, F.J. (2020), “Meeting, mating, and intermediating: how incubators can overcome weak network problems in entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Research Policy, Vol. 49 No. 1, 103884.

Ward (1986), Keeping the Family Business Healthy: How to Plan for Continuing Growth, Profitability, and Family Leadership, 1st ed., Jossey-Bass Publishers, San Francisco, California.

Welter, F., Baker, T., Audretsch, D.B. and Gartner, W.B. (2017), “Everyday entrepreneurship—a call for entrepreneurship research to embrace entrepreneurial diversity”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 41 No. 3, pp. 311-321, doi: 10.1111/etap.12258.

Westlund, H. and Bolton, R. (2003), “Local social capital and entrepreneurship”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 77-113, doi: 10.1023/a:1025024009072.

Wurth, B., Stam, E. and Spigel, B. (2022), “Toward an entrepreneurial ecosystem research program”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 46 No. 3, pp. 729-778, doi: 10.1177/1042258721998948.

Yilmaz, Y., Raetze, S., de Groote, J. and Kammerlander, N. (2024), “Resilience in family businesses: a systematic literature review”, Family Business Review, Vol. 37 No. 1, 08944865231223372, doi: 10.1177/08944865231223372.

Zahra, S.A. (2010), “Harvesting family firms' organizational social capital: a relational perspective”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 47 No. 2, pp. 345-366, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2009.00894.x.

Zellweger, T. and Sieger, P. (2010), “Entrepreneurial orientation in long-lived family firms”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 38 No. 1, pp. 67-84, doi: 10.1007/s11187-010-9267-6.

Zimmerman, M.A. and Zeitz, G.J. (2002), “Beyond survival: achieving new venture growth by building legitimacy”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 27 No. 3, pp. 414-431, doi: 10.5465/amr.2002.7389921.

References

Ács, Z.J., Autio, E. and Szerb, L. (2014), “National systems of entrepreneurship: measurement issues and policy implications”, Research Policy, Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 476-494, doi: 10.1016/j.respol.2013.08.016.

Arregle, J.-L., Hitt, M.A., Sirmon, D.G. and Very, P. (2007), “The development of organizational social capital: attributes of family firms”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 44 No. 1, pp. 73-95, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2007.00665.x.

Benavides-Salazar, C., Iturrioz-Landart, C., Aragón-Amonarriz, C. and Ibañez-Romero, A. (2022), “The role of entrepreneurial families in entrepreneurial ecosystems: the family social capital approach”, Journal of Entrepreneurship in Emerging Economies, Vol. 14 No. 6, pp. 1001-1032, doi: 10.1108/jeee-11-2020-0416.

Bergman, B.J. and McMullen, J.S. (2022), “Helping entrepreneurs help themselves: a review and relational research agenda on entrepreneurial support organizations”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 46 No. 3, pp. 688-728, doi: 10.1177/10422587211028736.

Bourdieu, P. (1987), “The forms of capital”, in The Sociology of Economic Life, Routledge, pp. 78-92.

Brown, R. and Mason, C. (2017), “Looking inside the spiky bits: a critical review and conceptualisation of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 49 No. 1, pp. 11-30, doi: 10.1007/s11187-017-9865-7.

Burt, R.S. (1992), Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition, Harvard University Press.

Burt, R.S. (2019), “Network disadvantaged entrepreneurs: density, hierarchy, and success in China and the West”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 43 No. 1, pp. 19-50, doi: 10.1177/1042258718783514.

Coleman, S. and Carsky, M. (1999), “Sources of capital for small family-owned businesses: evidence from the national survey of small business finances”, Family Business Review, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 73-85, doi: 10.1111/j.1741-6248.1999.00073.x.

Daniel, L.J., De Villiers Scheepers, M.J., Miles, M.P. and De Klerk, S. (2022), “Understanding entrepreneurial ecosystems using complex adaptive systems theory: getting the big picture for economic development, practice, and policy”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 34 Nos 9-10, pp. 911-934, doi: 10.1080/08985626.2022.2083691.

Feld, B. (2012), Startup Communities: Building an Entrepreneurial Ecosystem in Your City, John Wiley & Sons, Hoboken, NJ.

Fotopoulos, G. (2023), “Knowledge spillovers, entrepreneurial ecosystems and the geography of high growth firms”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 47 No. 5, pp. 1877-1914, doi: 10.1177/10422587221111732.

Gedajlovic, E., Honig, B., Moore, C.B., Payne, G.T. and Wright, M. (2013), “Social capital and entrepreneurship: a schema and research agenda”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 37 No. 3, pp. 455-478, doi: 10.1111/etap.12042.

Hadjielias, E., Hughes, M. and Scholes, L. (2022), “External crises and family social capital reconfiguration: insights from the European debt crisis and the Covid-19 pandemic”, Family Business Review, Vol. 35 No. 3, pp. 275-305, doi: 10.1177/08944865221113136.

Hruskova, M., Mason, C. and Herzog, S. (2022), “Mapping entrepreneurship support organisations: an examination of the ‘cluttered landscape’ critique”, Local Economy: The Journal of the Local Economy Policy Unit, Vol. 37 No. 7, pp. 541-563, doi: 10.1177/02690942231173655.

Isenberg, D. (2010), “The big idea: how to start an entrepreneurial revolution”, Harvard Business Review, (June, 2010 Issue).

Kwon, S. and Adler, P. (2014), “Social capital: maturation of a field of research”, Academy of Management Review, Vol. 39 No. 4, pp. 412-422, doi: 10.5465/amr.2014.0210.

Lester, R.H. and Cannella, A.A. (2006), “Interorganizational familiness: how family firms use interlocking directorates to build community–level social capital”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 30 No. 6, pp. 755-775, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2006.00149.x.

Long, R.G. (2011), “Commentary: social exchange in building, modelling, and managing family social capital”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 35 No. 6, pp. 1229-1234, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2011.00500.x.

Long, R. and Mathews, K. (2011), “Ethics in the family firm: cohesion through reciprocity and exchange”, Business Ethics Quarterly, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 287-308, doi: 10.5840/beq201121217.

Malecki, E.J. (2018), “Entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Geography Compass, Vol. 12 No. 3, e12359, doi: 10.1111/gec3.12359.

Neumeyer, X., Santos, S.C. and Morris, M.H. (2019), “Who is left out: exploring social boundaries in entrepreneurial ecosystems”, The Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 44 No. 2, pp. 462-484, doi: 10.1007/s10961-018-9694-0.

Nicotra, M., Romano, M., Del Giudice, M. and Schillaci, C.E. (2018), “The causal relation between entrepreneurial ecosystem and productive entrepreneurship: a measurement framework”, The Journal of Technology Transfer, Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 640-673, doi: 10.1007/s10961-017-9628-2.

Pearson, A.W., Carr, J.C. and Shaw, J.C. (2008), “Toward a theory of familiness: a social capital perspective”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 32 No. 6, pp. 949-969, doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6520.2008.00265.x.

Portes, A. (1998), “Social capital: its origins and applications in modern sociology”, Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 24, pp. 1-24, doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.24.1.1.

Pugh, R., Soetanto, D., Jack, S.L. and Hamilton, E. (2019), “Developing local entrepreneurial ecosystems through integrated learning initiatives: the Lancaster case”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 56 No. 2, pp. 833-847, doi: 10.1007/s11187-019-00271-5.

Putnam, R.D. (1993), “The prosperous community: social capital and public life”, The American Prospect, Vol. 4 No. 13, pp. 1-11.

Putnam, R.D. (2002), Democracies in Flux: The Evolution of Social Capital in Contemporary Society, Oxford University Press, London.

Roundy, P.T. (2017), “Social entrepreneurship and entrepreneurial ecosystems: complementary or disjoint phenomena?”, International Journal of Social Economics, Vol. 44 No. 9, pp. 1252-1267, doi: 10.1108/ijse-02-2016-0045.

Ryan, P., Giblin, M., Buciuni, G. and Kogler, D.F. (2020), “The role of MNEs in the genesis and growth of a resilient entrepreneurial ecosystem”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 33 Nos 1-2, pp. 36-53, doi: 10.1080/08985626.2020.1734260.

Sanchez-Ruiz, P., Daspit, J.J., Holt, D.T. and Rutherford, M.W. (2019), “Family social capital in the family firm: a taxonomic classification, relationships with outcomes, and directions for advancement”, Family Business Review, Vol. 32 No. 2, pp. 131-153, doi: 10.1177/0894486519836833.

Scheidgen, K. (2020), “Degrees of integration: how a fragmented entrepreneurial ecosystem promotes different types of entrepreneurs”, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, Vol. 33 Nos 1-2, pp. 1-26, doi: 10.1080/08985626.2020.1734263.

Schrijvers, M., Stam, E. and Bosma, N. (2024), “Figuring it out: configurations of high-performing entrepreneurial ecosystems in Europe”, Regional Studies, Vol. 58 No. 5, pp. 1096-1110, doi: 10.1080/00343404.2023.2226727.

Sorenson, R.L., Goodpaster, K.E., Hedberg, P.R. and Yu, A. (2009), “The family point of view, family social capital, and firm performance: an exploratory test”, Family Business Review, Vol. 22 No. 3, pp. 239-253, doi: 10.1177/0894486509332456.

Spigel, B. (2017), “The relational organization of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 41 No. 1, pp. 49-72, doi: 10.1111/etap.12167.

Spigel, B. (2020), Entrepreneurial Ecosystems: Theory, Practice and Futures, Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham; Northampton, MA.

Spigel, B. (2022), “Examining the cohesiveness and nestedness entrepreneurial ecosystems: evidence from British FinTechs”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 59 No. 4, pp. 1381-1399, doi: 10.1007/s11187-021-00589-z.

Spigel, B. and Harrison, R. (2018), “Toward a process theory of entrepreneurial ecosystems: toward a process theory of entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 151-168, doi: 10.1002/sej.1268.

Spigel, B., Kitagawa, F. and Mason, C. (2020), “A manifesto for researching entrepreneurial ecosystems”, Local Economy: The Journal of the Local Economy Policy Unit, Vol. 35 No. 5, pp. 482-495, doi: 10.1177/0269094220959052.

Stam, E. (2015), “Entrepreneurial ecosystems and regional policy: a sympathetic critique”, European Planning Studies, Vol. 23 No. 9, pp. 1759-1769, doi: 10.1080/09654313.2015.1061484.

Stasa, M. and Machek, O. (2022), “Social capital in the family business literature: a systematic review and future research agenda”, Family Business Review, Vol. 35 No. 4, pp. 415-441, doi: 10.1177/08944865221125520.

Theodoraki, C., Messeghem, K. and Rice, M.P. (2018), “A social capital approach to the development of sustainable entrepreneurial ecosystems: an explorative study”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 51 No. 1, pp. 153-170, doi: 10.1007/s11187-017-9924-0.

Thompson, T.A., Purdy, J.M. and Ventresca, M.J. (2018), “How entrepreneurial ecosystems take form: evidence from social impact initiatives in Seattle”, Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, Vol. 12 No. 1, pp. 96-116, doi: 10.1002/sej.1285.

Wagner, M., Schaltegger, S., Hansen, E.G. and Fichter, K. (2019), “University-linked programmes for sustainable entrepreneurship and regional development: how and with what impact?”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 56 No. 3, pp. 1141-1158, doi: 10.1007/s11187-019-00280-4.

Wurth, B., Stam, E. and Spigel, B. (2022), “Toward an entrepreneurial ecosystem research program”, Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Vol. 46 No. 3, pp. 729-778, doi: 10.1177/1042258721998948.

Yates, V.A., Vardaman, J.M. and Chrisman, J.J. (2023), “Social network research in the family business literature: a review and integration”, Small Business Economics, Vol. 60 No. 4, pp. 1323-1345, doi: 10.1007/s11187-022-00665-y.

Zahra, S.A. (2010), “Harvesting family firms' organizational social capital: a relational perspective”, Journal of Management Studies, Vol. 47 No. 2, pp. 345-366, doi: 10.1111/j.1467-6486.2009.00894.x.

Acknowledgements

Samuel Appleton would like to thank the supporting talent in research programme (STARS) (grant no. STARS21AZ1DOTEDIGIPASW) for the financial support.

Corresponding author

Samuel Wayne Appleton can be contacted at: samuel.appleton@unibg.it

Related articles