Time-varying parameters in monetary policy rules: a GMM approach

Christina Anderl (London South Bank University, London, UK)
Guglielmo Maria Caporale (Brunel University London, London, UK)

Journal of Economic Studies

ISSN: 0144-3585

Article publication date: 30 January 2024

393

Abstract

Purpose

The article aims to establish whether the degree of aversion to inflation and the responsiveness to deviations from potential output have changed over time.

Design/methodology/approach

This paper assesses time variation in monetary policy rules by applying a time-varying parameter generalised methods of moments (TVP-GMM) framework.

Findings

Using monthly data until December 2022 for five inflation targeting countries (the UK, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, Sweden) and five countries with alternative monetary regimes (the US, Japan, Denmark, the Euro Area, Switzerland), we find that monetary policy has become more averse to inflation and more responsive to the output gap in both sets of countries over time. In particular, there has been a clear shift in inflation targeting countries towards a more hawkish stance on inflation since the adoption of this regime and a greater response to both inflation and the output gap in most countries after the global financial crisis, which indicates a stronger reliance on monetary rules to stabilise the economy in recent years. It also appears that inflation targeting countries pay greater attention to the exchange rate pass-through channel when setting interest rates. Finally, monetary surprises do not seem to be an important determinant of the evolution over time of the Taylor rule parameters, which suggests a high degree of monetary policy transparency in the countries under examination.

Originality/value

It provides new evidence on changes over time in monetary policy rules.

Keywords

Citation

Anderl, C. and Caporale, G.M. (2024), "Time-varying parameters in monetary policy rules: a GMM approach", Journal of Economic Studies, Vol. 51 No. 9, pp. 148-176. https://doi.org/10.1108/JES-06-2023-0289

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2024, Christina Anderl and Guglielmo Maria Caporale

License

Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode


1. Introduction

In recent decades, monetary authorities in major central banks have managed to achieve low and stable inflation rates, which have been seen as a direct result of the adoption of monetary policy rules. Taylor rules appear to explain monetary policy well in inflation targeting countries (Taylor and Davradakis, 2006; Çağlayan and Astar, 2010; Neuenkirch and Tillmann, 2014), but even central banks which operate alternative monetary regimes are known to follow at times such a rule to stabilise inflation (Woodford, 2001; Orphanides, 2003; Sauer and Sturm, 2007; Sanchez-Robles and Maza, 2013; Nitschka and Markov, 2016). However, regardless of the type of monetary regime in place, policymakers and their objectives can change over time, and thus their monetary stance can also change to respond effectively to shocks.

Several studies have recognised this fact and investigated possible shifts in the parameters of monetary policy rules over time. Sub-period analyses in this context provide evidence for changing interest rate policies, but tend to focus primarily on the US, which experienced such changes during the Volcker-Greenspan era (Judd and Rudebusch, 1998; Clarida et al., 2000; Orphanides, 2004), while more complex regime-switching models have been used to capture shifts in the Taylor rule parameters in other developed as well as emerging economies (Zheng et al., 2012; Alba and Wang, 2017; Caporale et al., 2018). Other studies, which employ maximum likelihood (ML) and Kalman filtering methods, report that time-varying parameter (TVP) Taylor rules explain monetary policy better than constant parameter ones (Kim and Nelson, 2006; Trecroci and Vassalli, 2010; Yüksel et al., 2013). However, as Partouche (2007) points out, Kalman filter methods are restrictive since they impose constraints on the form of heteroscedasticity and the correlations between the disturbances and the regressors; he proposes using instead a version of the generalised methods of moments (GMM) which allows for time variation to capture changes in monetary policy rules and applies this framework to analyse the behaviour of the federal reserve.

The present paper contributes to this area of the literature by assessing how the stance of monetary authorities towards inflation and output stabilisation changes over time, as reflected in the Taylor rule parameters. We apply the procedure developed by Partouche (2007) to a greater range of countries with different monetary frameworks, and for an extended sample including recent crisis periods characterised by monetary policy shifts. More specifically, the analysis applies a TVP-GMM framework as in Partouche (2007) to estimate Taylor rules for five inflation targeting countries, i.e. the UK, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and Sweden. For comparison purposes, the exercise is also carried out for a set of countries which have instead adopted alternative monetary regimes but followed a Taylor rule at times, namely the US, Japan, Denmark, the Euro Area and Switzerland. Both standard and augmented forward-looking TVP Taylor rules are estimated and assessed against constant parameter rules. Importantly, the GMM method allows us to capture gradual changes in the monetary stance over long time periods which constant parameter rules or sub-sample analyses are unable to detect. Compared to other time-varying methods, the one used in this paper has several advantages; specifically, it uses smoothed estimates rather than filtered ones, does not impose any priors and deals with the endogeneity problem that arises from the presence of expected values in the regressors.

2. Literature review

Several monetary authorities around the world have been operating an inflation targeting regime since the 1990s, while central banks with alternative monetary frameworks have at times targeted the inflation rate according to a monetary policy rule. The well-known Taylor rule (Taylor, 1993, 1999b) describes monetary policy as an interest rate setting mechanism to respond to deviations of inflation and output from their targets. It has been found that monetary authorities who follow a Taylor rule experience greater macroeconomic stability (Fregert and Jonung, 2008; Çağlayan and Astar, 2010; Beaudry and Ruge-Murcia, 2017; Zhu et al., 2021). Further evidence suggests that monetary policy can best be described by a Taylor rule even in countries which did not adopt an inflation targeting framework, for instance the US (Woodford, 2001; Orphanides, 2003), the Euro Area (Sauer and Sturm, 2007; Sanchez-Robles and Maza, 2013), Switzerland (Nitschka and Markov, 2016) and the seven largest Latin American countries (Moura and De Carvalho, 2010).

It should be noted that, despite the increasingly widespread use of Taylor rules by monetary authorities, some issues arise when such a policy framework is adopted. For instance, some studies claim that the use of Taylor rules does not always generate the best economic outcomes. In particular, Crowley and Hudgins (2021) used a wavelet-based control model to compare the US Taylor rule to an optimal control policy rule. While the results indicate that the Taylor rule generates higher interest rates in a low inflation environment under both a hawkish and a dovish regime, they should be seen as mainly illustrative since the wavelet-based model is not fully calibrated. There are also other disadvantages to using Taylor rules. These include: the difficulty of estimating some unobservable variables such as the output gap; the limited availability of real time data on output and prices which would enable monetary authorities to respond more effectively to changes in those variables; the lack of parameters capturing directly its impact on the financial sector, for instance through its effects on the balance sheets of financial institutions.

A further issue concerns the use of monetary policy rules versus exercising monetary discretion. There is an ample debate in the literature, which is summarised by Taylor (2017) in his review paper discussing the main arguments of both sides. He concludes that a more systematic approach to monetary policy generates better economic outcomes since proposals for monetary policy rules tend to be based on the findings of empirical research and have improved over time. However, central banks are advised to improve their reporting on how these rules are being used.

It is important to point out that various specifications of the Taylor rule have been considered in the existing literature, and also that various methods have been used for their estimation. The augmented Taylor rule, which includes the real exchange rate in addition to the inflation and output gaps, seems to explain monetary policy well in open economies (Batini et al., 2003; Adolfson, 2007; Aizenman et al., 2011), and forward-looking rules in particular have found much support in the literature (Batini and Haldane, 1998; Fendel et al., 2011; Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, 2011). The methods used include ordinary least squares (OLS), ML and system methods (Cochrane, 2011). The seminal paper by Clarida et al. (1998) was the first to apply the GMM framework to forward-looking Taylor rules; its findings suggest that monetary policy can be explained accurately using this method in the case of the G3 (Germany, Japan and the US) and to some extent in that of the E3 (the UK, France and Italy). Subsequent empirical studies found that GMM is the most suitable methodology to deal with endogeneity when estimating monetary policy rules (Florens et al., 2001; Yau, 2010; Rühl, 2015).

It must be stressed that monetary policy objectives can change over time. Therefore a key issue in this context is the adoption of a modelling framework which allows for time variation in the Taylor rule parameters. Judd and Rudebusch (1998), for instance, performed a sub-sample analysis of the Fed’s policy rule using OLS and found substantial differences in the parameters between the sub-periods considered. Clarida et al. (2000) assessed forward-looking Taylor rules in a GMM framework and reported significant monetary policy regime shifts for the Fed during the Volcker-Greenspan era. Similar results were obtained by Orphanides (2004) when including real-time information in the model. McCulloch (2007) used an adaptive least squares approach and confirmed previous findings that the parameters in the US Taylor rule are not constant. Conrad and Eife (2012) performed rolling window regressions to obtain TVP estimates of the Taylor rule reaction function for the Fed, their findings also explaining changes in the US inflation-gap persistence. Papadamou et al. (2018) applied the GMM method to conduct sub-sample analysis for a period including the global financial crisis and found evidence of substantial asymmetries in the ECB’s reaction function. Orphanides and Williams (2005) adopted a TVP vector autoregressive (VAR) framework and found that their model provided a good description of US monetary policy. Similar results were obtained by Sims and Zha (2006), who employed a structural VAR model with TVP. Several studies have modelled time variation by using regime-switching models. Caporale et al. (2018), for instance, estimated augmented Taylor rules for selected emerging economies by using a Threshold GMM, which seems to capture well the behaviour of central banks in those countries. Markov-switching and Smooth Transition applications also provide ample evidence for parameter shifts in the monetary policy rule for various developed and emerging economies (Perruchoud, 2009; Alcidi et al., 2011; Zheng et al., 2012; Alba and Wang, 2017).

More recent studies employ a Kalman filtering approach to model policy shifts and structural changes in the Taylor rule. Trecroci and Vassalli (2010) found that a TVP specification using the Kalman filter outperforms the constant parameter one by capturing changes in the monetary policy rule for the US, the UK, Germany, France and Italy. Yüksel et al. (2013) applied the extended Kalman filter to estimate TVPs in the monetary policy rule in the case of Turkey, and found that this specification outperforms the standard one for the central bank reaction function. Boivin (2006) used the Kalman filter to estimate a likelihood function for the US and found evidence of gradual changes in the Taylor rule parameters. Using a two-step ML method, Kim and Nelson (2006) showed that US monetary policy can be classified according to three distinct periods with different Taylor rule parameters rather than the two identified previously.

The effectiveness of monetary policy rules also depends on how they are perceived by the public. Bauer et al. (2022) analysed this issue in the case of the US and noticed significant changes over time. Specifically, the output coefficient decreases (increases) towards the end (beginning) of a tightening cycle and monetary easings tend to be implemented quickly, while tightenings occur more gradually. Bianchi et al. (2022) documented large shifts in the parameters of the US monetary policy rule over the past few decades and concluded that infrequent changes in the monetary stance can lead to persistent shifts in the real interest rate and asset valuations. Bauer and Swanson (2023) estimated a time-varying monetary policy rule for the Fed using weighted recursive least squares and found that the Fed’s response to both the inflation and output gap has increased over the past 3 decades. Using a ML estimation method, Gürkaynak et al. (2023) provided evidence that weak monetary rules not satisfying the Taylor principle lead to out-of-control inflation.

Although most of the abovementioned studies suggest that the Kalman filter captures gradual variations in the Taylor rule better than constant parameter models, this approach suffers from a major drawback, since it imposes constraints on the form of heteroscedasticity of the error term. To address this issue, Partouche (2007) developed a GMM framework with TVPs to assess parameter shifts in the monetary policy rule. This model has the advantage that it is robust to heteroscedasticity, unlike Kalman filtering approaches, and is applied in the present study to carry out the empirical analysis.

3. Empirical framework

3.1 The Taylor rule

Taylor (1993, 1998) proposes the following monetary rule to capture the behaviour of a central bank:

(1)it=πt+a(πtπ¯)+byt+rt
where it is the policy rate, πt is the inflation rate and π¯ the inflation target, yt is the output gap, i.e. the deviation of real gross domestic product (GDP) from target, and rt is the equilibrium real interest rate. The size of the parameters a and b indicates the central bank’s degree of inflation aversion (higher a) compared to unemployment aversion (higher b), and were originally set equal to 1.5 and 0.5 respectively in Taylor (1998).

The empirical Taylor rule estimated in this paper is a forward-looking one of the following form:

(2)it=r¯+φπk=13(Et1πt+kπ¯)+φyk=13(Et1yt+k)+ut
where it is the interest rate set by the central bank, and r¯ is the equilibrium real interest rate, which is unobserved and is measured by the constant in the regression as in most studies (e.g. Razzak, 2003; Adanur Aklan and Nargelecekenler, 2008; Belke and Klose, 2009; Judd and Rudebusch, 2020). πt+k and yt+k are the k-period ahead forecasts of inflation and the output gap respectively, and ut is an error term. Instead of contemporaneous or lagged values of the variables, we include proxies for forecasts based on the 3-month lead average for the inflation rate and the output gap. Since backward-looking specifications of the Taylor rule have been rejected in favour of forward-looking ones, the above should capture monetary policy more accurately (Clarida et al., 1998).

The Taylor rule given by equation (2) is suitable for closed economies; however, in open economies, monetary policy can be influenced by the behaviour of the real exchange rate, which has been considered in several studies (Svensson, 2000; Caporale et al., 2018; Tiryaki et al., 2018). Therefore, we also estimate the following augmented Taylor rule:

(3)it=r¯+φπk=13(Et1πt+kπ¯)+φyk=13(Et1yt+k)++φqk=13(Et1qt+k)+ut
where qt+k is the forward-looking real effective exchange rate. We use the generalised methods of moments (GMM) framework to estimate the Taylor rules in equations (2) and (3).

3.2 The constant parameter GMM

The GMM is a semi-parametric framework which is a suitable alternative to OLS approaches in cases where the error term is correlated with the regressors. This is likely to happen in forward-looking models which include (expected) future rather than contemporaneous values of the regressors; these are then correlated with the expectational errors usually contained in the error term (Taylor and Davradakis, 2006).

The estimation of a GMM model with constant parameters δ follows a two-step procedure as outlined in Clarida et al. (2000). Let Zt denote a vector of q instruments which satisfy the orthogonality condition E(Zu)=0. The GMM framework with an optimal weighting matrix S accounts for any possible serial correlation in the error term ut. The weighting matrix S depends on the population moments and the model parameters δ:

(4)minδ{(t=1T(xtztδ)Zt)S(t=1T(xtztδ)Zt)}
where xt stands for the endogenous variable in the model (in our case the policy rate), and zt for the explanatory variables. The moment conditions in the static parameter case are:
(5)E(xtztδ|It1)=0E((xtztδ)Zt)=0

For cases where the number of instruments Zt exceeds the number of parameters, overidentifying restrictions need to be imposed. We use the Sargan Test (Sargan, 1958) for the validity of the instruments in the overidentified case. Since this method requires all variables to be stationary, we carry out unit root tests for all of them, specifically the Dickey-Fuller generalised least squares (DF-GLS) test, the Zivot and Andrews (2002) test allowing for a break in the intercept and/or the trend, and the Lee and Strazicich (2003) Lagrange multiplier test allowing for a structural break under both the null and the alternative hypothesis.

To detect the possible presence of time-variation, one can estimate in the first instance a constant coefficient GMM model for some suitably identified sub-samples. This is often done in the literature (see, e.g. Orphanides, 2004; Papadamou et al., 2018) to distinguish between periods characterised by different policy regimes. Following this approach, we split the sample into sub-periods, first doing visual inspection of the inflation and policy rate series to determine the break points and next applying a more rigorous method, namely the supF structural break test developed by Andrews (1993), to detect the unknown break points.

3.3 A GMM model with time-varying parameters

While sub-period analysis can provide some evidence on time-variation in the Taylor rule parameters, the choice of the break dates could be arbitrary and the sub-periods too short for reliable statistical inference. Furthermore, this approach can only capture discrete parameter shifts. By contrast, the method suggested by Partouche (2007) allows for gradually evolving parameters within a GMM framework. Specifically, the minimisation problem in equation (4) can be written as follows using the Lagrange multiplier:

(6)min(δi)i[0,T](1Tt=1T(xtztδt)Zt)S(1Tt=1T(xtztδt)Zt)+1Tt=1TT2δtRδt

with the underlying statistical model:

(7){xt=ztδt+vtE(Ztvt)=0δt=δt1+etetN(0,Qe)
where R is the Lagrange multiplier and Qe is the covariance matrix of the innovation of the time-varying coefficient vector δt. Note that δt=(φ0,φi,φπ,φy,φq) is assumed to follow a random walk. The corresponding moment conditions in the time-varying case are:
E(xtztδt|It1)=0E((xtztδt)Zt)=0
where the subscript t denotes the time-varying element.

The problem in equation (6) can be solved using non-parametric smoothing splines rather than the semi-parametric constant parameter GMM (Craven and Wahba, 1978). This method allows to carry out the estimation independently of a specific statistical model. The values of R and S are then chosen so as to obtain the estimates with the lowest mean squared error (MSE).

Modelling time variation in the parameters of the GMM directly is a more flexible method than sub-period analysis, and it does not face the issue of the small numbers of observations within sub-periods. Unlike the Kalman filtering approach suggested by Kim and Nelson (2006), which requires assuming a specific form of heteroscedasticity, the TVP-GMM framework is robust to the type of heteroscedasticity in the errors. To deal with possible autocorrelation, Stock and Watson (1998) suggest using an autoregressive filter, whilst the endogeneity problem can be addressed by using the median unbiased estimate calculation developed by Stock and Watson (1998).

Partouche (2007) recommends checking robustness with respect to the covariance matrix Qu=μ2T2Q¯. In particular, in the TVP-GMM model, the variance of the innovations Q¯ is constrained to be diagonal. Following Partouche (2007), we redo the estimation after removing this restriction. Finally, as an additional robustness test, we also estimate TVPs in a backward-looking version of the standard and augmented Taylor rules by entering the first lags of the regressors.

4. Data and empirical results

4.1 Data description

We estimate the Taylor rule for countries which adopted an inflation targeting regime in the early 1990s, namely the UK, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and Sweden, as well as for a set of countries with alternative monetary regimes which, however, have at times followed a policy rule, more precisely, the US, Japan, Denmark, the Euro Area and Switzerland. We use monthly data from January 1985 up until December 2022 for all countries except the Euro Area, for which data are only available from January 1999 [1]. The classification of countries into inflation targeters and those with alternative monetary regimes is made on the basis of which ones adopted the inflation targeting regime during the 1990s and is consistent with those found in the existing literature (Mishkin and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2001). While there are some minor disagreements concerning the defining characteristics of the inflation targeting framework (Sterne, 2000), in general countries are classified on the basis of the clarity and credibility of their commitment to the target over the entire sample range under consideration; according to this criterion the first set of countries in our case are full-fledged inflation targeters, while the others operate an implicit price stability anchor (Carare and Stone, 2006). Full-fledged inflation targeters make a full commitment to the inflation target and tend to have a higher level of credibility due to an institutionalised transparent monetary policy framework. Countries with an implicit price stability anchor are able to maintain low and stable inflation without displaying full transparency in relation to an inflation target. This allows these countries to pursue dual objectives of output and price stabilisation.

The consumer price inflation (CPI) series have been obtained from the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) consumer prices dataset for all countries and used to construct the inflation gap [2]. The interest rate series is the central bank policy rate which has been taken from the BIS Central Bank Policy Rates dataset. The output series is the organisation for economic co-operation and development (OECD) normalised GDP series obtained from the federal reserve bank of St Louis economic database (FRED). The Hodrick-Prescott filter is used to estimate the output gap [3]. The real effective exchange rate series have been retrieved from the BIS effective exchange rate narrow indices dataset. We also obtain from Bloomberg central bank announcements together with forecasts of interest rate decisions; this allows us to establish whether an announcement included an unexpected component St, which is the difference between what the central bank announces (At) and what the market expected (Ft), i.e. St=AtFt. A value of St which is different from zero indicates that the central bank is implementing stronger monetary policy measures than anticipated by the market. Details regarding the announcement dates for all countries are included in Online Appendix A. This information helps to interpret the evolution of the Taylor rule parameters over time. As instruments in both the constant and the TVP-GMM models we use a constant and the first, third, sixth and twelfth lag of the interest rate, the inflation rate and the output gap to estimate the standard Taylor rule as in equation (2), and for the augmented Taylor rule as in equation (3) we include the first, third, sixth and twelfth lag of the real effective exchange rate as additional instruments.

Figure 1 plots the inflation and interest rate series for each country over time. Vertical lines correspond to the main shifts in monetary policy. For inflation targeting countries, this includes the point when the inflation targeting regime was officially adopted, but also turning points when the attitude towards inflation changed – for instance, immediately after the global financial crisis, when several countries resorted to unconventional monetary policies, such as quantitative easing and forward guidance. For countries with alternative monetary policy regimes the vertical lines indicate points in time when the respective central banks began to use actively a monetary policy rule to target the inflation rate. Monetary policy appears to have been contractionary in almost all countries up until the global financial crisis, when it became more accommodating. Noticeable changes in inflation and policy rate behaviour occurred also as a result of the recent Covid-19 pandemic. However, a split of the full sample into subsamples around these dates would result in insufficient data points to allow for meaningful statistical inference.

Before starting the empirical estimation we test for stationarity of the individual time series since this is a requirement of the GMM model. Table 1 reports the results of the three unit roots tests we carry out. The DF-GLS and the Lee and Strazicich tests indicate that all series are stationary except the real effective exchange rate ones, which are integrated of order I(1) and therefore are entered into the model in first differences; however, the Zivot-Andrews test implies that in some cases the policy and inflation rates are also integrated of order I(1).

This is not an uncommon finding; nevertheless, many authors, such as Clarida et al. (1998, 2000), treat the policy rate and in some cases also the inflation rate as stationary, which they view as a reasonable assumption to estimate the Taylor rules without too much information loss from differencing. For this reason, and given the fact that the majority of the unit root tests we employ suggest that both these variables are stationary, we also treat them as such.

4.2 Results for the constant parameter taylor rule

For a start we estimate the standard and augmented Taylor rules using the constant parameter GMM for the entire sample and report the results in Table 2 for all countries. On first inspection one can note that the coefficients on the inflation and output gap are not particularly close to the values of 1.5 and 0.5 suggested by Taylor (1998). The inflation gap parameters range between 1.09 and 2.23 and the output gap ones between 0.32 and 0.82 for the countries in our sample. The real effective exchange rate included in the augmented Taylor rule seems to play an important role mainly in the case of Australia and Sweden, whilst it is less relevant in the other cases.

No significant differences emerge in the Taylor rule parameters between inflation targeting countries and those which adopted an alternative monetary regime instead. For the US, the coefficients are higher than those reported by some previous studies such as Österholm (2005) and Castro (2011), but very close to those estimated for the post-1982 period by Silva et al. (2021). They also seem to be higher for the case of Australia and Sweden compared, for instance, to those in Österholm (2005), while for the UK, New Zealand and the Euro Area they are lower than those reported in the previous literature (Castro, 2011; Kendall and Ng, 2013), although for sample periods rather different from that of the present study.

Next we perform sub-period analysis for both types of Taylor rules. At first, the sample is split into two sub-samples for each country according to the break dates identified from visual inspection of the series and corresponding to the main policy shift in each country (see Online Appendix B for details); note that creating more sub-samples would make the inference unreliable owing to the small number of observations in each case. Table 3 reports these results. The parameters seem to have changed significantly in most countries. More specifically, the inflation gap coefficients are lower in both sub-periods than the full-sample ones and now range between 0.38 and 1.32, whilst the output gap coefficients are mainly insignificant and range between 0.10 and 0.89.

In sub-period I, which includes the time period at least up until the global financial crisis for all countries, monetary authorities appear to be rather responsive to inflation, regardless of the type of monetary regime in place. In sub-period II, which includes the post-financial crisis period, the inflation aversion of all central banks seems to have decreased. In some cases (the UK, New Zealand, Sweden, Japan and the Euro Area) the Taylor rule estimates indicate lower responsiveness to output and inflation changes in the period after the global financial crisis, which has been frequently characterised by unconventional monetary policies and during which countries not identifying themselves as inflation targeters (Japan, Denmark, the Euro Area and Switzerland) have cut their policy rates below zero, the coefficient on the real interest rate becoming negative.

The above sub-period analysis is based on break points chosen through visual inspection. A more rigorous approach is followed next by testing for structural breaks by means of the supF test by Andrews (1993) and splitting the sample accordingly. The test results are reported in Online Appendix C, while the sub-period estimates are displayed in Tables 4 and 5 for the standard and augmented Taylor rules, respectively. In contrast to the previous set of results based on visual inspection, it now seems that in all countries monetary authorities started reacting more strongly to both inflation and output gaps after the global financial crisis, their overall stance becoming more hawkish following the global financial crisis, but again some of the sub-samples are too short for reliable inference.

The above analysis provides some preliminary evidence about changes over time in the Taylor rule parameters. In the next step we estimate the TVP-GMM model to shed further light on the evolution of the parameters in the Taylor rule over the entire time period.

4.3 Results for the time-varying parameter Taylor rule

Figures 2 and 3 display the TVPs of the forward-looking standard Taylor rule for inflation targeting countries and for those with alternative monetary regimes, respectively. While some of the parameter shifts coincide with those suggested by the structural break analysis, the time-varying approach identifies more shifts than both the structural break tests or the initial visual inspection. These results imply that most countries have become more responsive to both inflation and the output gap over time. In inflation targeting countries, the adoption of inflation targeting coincides with an increase in the inflation coefficient (which is particularly sharp in the case of the UK, Canada and New Zealand), in contrast to the decrease estimated when doing sub-period analysis based on visual inspection. This shift also corresponds to a period of lower inflation and lower interest rates in all inflation targeting countries (see Figure 1). It appears that the time-varying Taylor rule captures the sharp increase in the response to inflation which occurred at the time of the adoption of the new policy rule, which was then followed by smaller parameter changes. This shift towards greater inflation stabilisation is what one would expect from monetary authorities which had made an explicit commitment to inflation targeting (Taylor, 1999a; Sergi and Hsing, 2010).

A second sharp rise in the inflation coefficient occurred after the global financial crisis in most countries. It seems that, regardless of the type of monetary regime, the crisis prompted central banks to put stronger emphasis on inflation and output stabilisation. Again this coincided with a shift towards lower inflation and policy rates in all countries (see Figure 1), which suggests that the increased emphasis on targeting inflation in the monetary policy rule was successful in reducing inflation. Consistently with the findings by Partouche (2007), our results indicate that monetary policy became more countercyclical over time, as indicated by the bigger coefficient on the output gap, which is a measure of the business cycle.

It is worth noting some important differences which can be observed between inflation targeting countries and those prioritising other monetary objectives. It appears that in the former the adoption of a new monetary rule coincides with an initial large increase in the response to inflation developments, whilst subsequently only very small changes in the inflation coefficient are implemented by monetary authorities. For instance, the reaction of inflation targeting countries to the global financial crisis was much more modest than that of countries with alternative monetary regimes, for which the inflation coefficient increased quite substantially around that time. The former showed a clear commitment to the Taylor rule over time, which might have resulted in higher central bank credibility in these countries compared to those which did not make an explicit commitment to price stabilisation and instead display greater economic discretion. However, it has to be noted that in countries with alternative monetary regimes the size of the coefficients may depend on many additional features of the economy (Taylor, 1999a). The inflation targeting framework allows countries to establish greater credibility leading to a lasting anchoring of inflation expectations. In fact, since the inflation target is a medium-term objective, inflation targeting central banks put great effort into managing inflation expectations, so that short-term deviations of inflation from the target do not result in a loss of credibility.

Next we examine in greater detail periods which exhibited large changes in the Taylor rule parameters. For instance, after 2013 there were increases in both the inflation and output coefficients in the US compared to the more inflation-focused earlier period following the adoption of an inflation targeting rule in 2012. This behaviour is consistent with the balanced approach to monetary policy advocated by Janet Yellen at the end of 2012. In the case of Australia there was a sharp decrease in the output coefficient after the global financial crisis. This finding is consistent with a more aggressive stance towards inflation coupled with a milder reaction to output, which the Reserve Bank of Australia adopted in response to the crisis (Lee et al., 2013). In general, most existing studies report a decline in the output gap coefficient for Australia over time (De Brouwer and Gilbert, 2005; Hudson and Vespignani, 2018). A sharp increase in the inflation coefficient can be observed in the case of the Swiss monetary rule in the early 1990s. During this time, the Swiss economy experienced rising inflation rates and a depreciation of the Swiss franc, which the Swiss National Bank addressed through monetary tightening. This move was inconsistent with achieving its money supply growth target of 2% and demonstrates the exercise of monetary discretion to economic developments by the monetary authority (Swiss National Bank, 2016).

It is well-known that the size of the Taylor rule coefficients strongly influences the transmission mechanism and the overall macroeconomic effects of monetary policy (Taylor, 1999a). Therefore it is crucial for central banks to understand which Taylor rule specification and parameter size is optimal at any given point in time with the aim of improving economic performance and achieving inflation stabilisation. They can learn from historical rules and economic outcomes in order to adopt a more systematic approach to monetary policy and choose optimal rules.

The standard Taylor rule is useful to assess monetary policy in closed economies, but in open economies inflation can be influenced by exchange rate changes through the exchange rate pass-through, which is why the real exchange rate should also be included in the Taylor rule. Of the countries in our sample only Switzerland and Japan are known officially to take the real exchange rate into account when setting interest rates. Figures 4 and 5 show the time-varying Taylor rule parameters for the forward-looking augmented Taylor rule which includes the real exchange rate for inflation targeting and non-targeting countries respectively. Central banks in former are now found to be more responsive to changes in the inflation as opposed to the output gap, whilst those in countries with alternative monetary regimes appear to be less responsive to either in the open-economy case. Therefore this evidence suggests differences between countries with strict inflation targeting mandates and those with discretionary monetary flexibility in the extent to which they take into account the exchange rate pass-through in their interest rate setting.

Finally, in order to investigate the possible impact of monetary surprises on the evolution of the Taylor rule parameters, in Online Appendix D we display the latter together with vertical bars corresponding to interest rate announcements with an unexpected component. In the case of Denmark, no such component could be identified in any announcement. As for the other countries, in most cases no clear linkage can be seen between unexpected interest rate announcements and shifts in the Taylor rule parameters; the exceptions are the UK and Japan, where the output gap parameter increases sharply in the aftermath of unexpected announcements in 2015, and the US, where the interest rate and inflation parameters exhibit a sizeable decrease and increase respectively after the arrival of unexpected announcements during the financial crisis, in 2008. Overall, the evidence suggests that central banks communicate their current and future policy objectives in a timely manner and that their announcements are consistent with the policy rule; as a result, monetary surprises do not appear to play a major role as drivers of the Taylor rule parameters. They can arise when the perceived responsiveness of the central bank to the economy is different from the actual one. Thus, changes in the Taylor rule parameters which are not expected by the public can be seen as monetary policy surprises. This type of imperfect information is often a cause rather than a result of the monetary surprise and can influence the transmission mechanism (Bauer and Swanson, 2023).

4.4 Robustness analysis

Following Partouche (2007), we check robustness by allowing the matrix Q¯ to be non-restricted. These results are reported in Online Appendix E and confirm robustness, especially in the case of the inflation and output gap parameters. Although central banks are known to respond to anticipated inflation instead of past inflation, as a further robustness check we also estimate backward-looking Taylor rules by including the first lag of all variables. These additional results are reported in Online Appendix F for both standard and augmented Taylor rules; compared to the forward-looking Taylor rules there are only slight differences in the inflation parameter estimates, particularly in non-targeting countries. The backward-looking rules seem to be less suitable to capture major shifts (such as the introduction of the inflation targeting regime) and display greater variation in the estimated Taylor rule parameters.

5. Conclusions

This paper assesses time variation in the monetary policy rules of inflation targeting countries (the UK, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and Sweden) and others with alternative monetary regimes but known to target inflation at times (the US, Japan, Denmark, the EuroArea and Switzerland). Initially, sub-period analysis was conducted using visual inspection as well as formal break tests to identify the break dates. Then, following Partouche (2007), a TVP-GMM framework was applied to estimate TVPs in forward-looking standard and augmented Taylor rules.

The results can be summarised as follows. First, monetary policy appears to have become more averse to inflation and more responsive to the output gap over time in both inflation targeting and non-targeting countries. In the former the shift to inflation targeting coincides with a sharp increase in the inflation coefficient in the Taylor rule. For both sets of countries, a sizeable shift occurred after the global financial crisis when monetary policy became more accommodating. Second, monetary policy has become more countercyclical in all countries over time, with an increased focus on stabilisation policies since the global financial crisis. Third, there seem to be differences between countries with strict inflation targeting mandates and those with discretionary monetary flexibility in terms of the extent to which the exchange rate pass-through channel for inflation is taken into account, the former set of countries paying greater attention to it. Fourth, the TVP framework is more informative than the sub-period analysis for detecting shifts in the parameters of the Taylor rule. Finally, monetary surprises do not seem to be an important determinant of their evolution over time, which suggests a high degree of monetary policy transparency in the countries under examination. On the whole, our findings provide extensive evidence that constant parameter Taylor rules cannot capture accurately the behaviour of monetary authorities. In particular, it is clear that, following the global financial crisis, central banks have started to put greater emphasis on inflation and output stabilisation, be they inflation targeters or not.

These findings have important implications for policymakers. First, reviewing past shifts in the Taylor rule parameters alongside the historical development of inflation can provide central banks with insights into the monetary policy transmission mechanism. This can be useful to formulate appropriate monetary policies going forward. Second, policymakers should continue to ensure a high degree of transparency by clearly communicating any changes in the Taylor rule parameters to the public, since our evidence shows that this reduces the size of monetary surprises related to the monetary stance. Third, it seems that in inflation targeting countries a smaller response of the monetary rule parameters to economic shocks is required to stabilise the economy than in those with alternative regimes since in the former central banks demonstrate a consistent commitment to inflation stabilisation over time and are likely to have greater credibility. Greater transparency in inflation targeting countries reduces uncertainty regarding inflation and the conduct of monetary policy, which allows inflation expectations to be anchored more permanently. Our findings clearly reflect this distinct advantage of the inflation targeting framework.

Figures

Inflation and policy rates

Figure 1.

Inflation and policy rates

Time-varying standard Taylor rule parameters for inflation targeting countries

Figure 2

Time-varying standard Taylor rule parameters for inflation targeting countries

Time-varying standard Taylor rule parameters for non-targeting countries

Figure 3

Time-varying standard Taylor rule parameters for non-targeting countries

Time-varying augmented Taylor rule parameters for inflation targeting countries

Figure 4

Time-varying augmented Taylor rule parameters for inflation targeting countries

Time-varying augmented Taylor rule parameters for non-targeting countries

Figure 5

Time-varying augmented Taylor rule parameters for non-targeting countries

DF-GLS, Zivot-Andrews (ZA) and Lee and Strazicich (LS) unit root test results for the individual series

DF-GLSZALSDF-GLSZALS
itit
United Kingdom−3.237**−2.309−5.901***−4.898***−9.377***−9.765***
Canada−3.784***−3.750−5.720***−4.680***−9.153***−9.381***
Australia−5.122***−2.897−6.236***−7.502***−7.449***−12.754***
New Zealand−3.552***−2.878−5.609***−5.025***−11.443***−12.821***
Sweden−3.361**−3.815−5.442***−11.951***−12.285***−12.383***
United States−3.084**−2.644−4.613**−11.670***−9.807***−5.330***
Japan−3.889***−4.797**−4.238**−11.415***−17.709***−25.812***
Denmark−3.303**−2.892−4.291**−4.072***−17.387***−17.154***
Euro-Area−3.168**−1.112−5.170***−10.758***−17.847***−17.662***
Switzerland−3.291**−3.040−3.002−6.561***−17.647***−11.876***
ytyt
United Kingdom−5.112***−6.114***−5.528***−6.681***−11.990***−6.509***
Canada−5.246***−5.331***−5.233***−10.136***−10.298***−10.083***
Australia−5.248***−5.214***−5.328***−4.590***−10.628***−10.636***
New Zealand−3.323**−6.430***−4.537***−6.580***−9.602***−8.915***
Sweden−5.970***−4.453**−5.558***−6.235***−7.350***−6.350***
United States−5.431***−5.707***−5.317***−7.660***−9.544***−9.598***
Japan−5.560***−5.240***−5.606***−6.038***−7.859***−7.312***
Denmark−4.154***−6.070***−4.742***−7.203***−8.891***−7.348***
Euro-Area−3.802***−4.425**−4.465**−11.715***−12.067***−12.458***
Switzerland−5.185***−4.845**−4.447**−6.443***−10.743***−6.799***
πtπt
United Kingdom−3.160**−4.166−4.832***−8.709***−12.397***−9.160***
Canada−5.141***−4.501**−6.807***−8.140***−10.373***−8.676***
Australia−3.327**−3.889−4.004**−5.589***−21.285***−21.347***
New Zealand−3.792***−3.519−3.664−6.394***−21.294***−6.543***
Sweden−3.504***−4.425**−3.681−5.597***−11.695***−11.699***
United States−4.084***−5.801***−5.406***−8.079***−12.165***−7.890***
Japan−4.951***−6.672***−5.085***−14.245***−13.612***−13.428***
Denmark−3.220**−2.831−4.125**−5.466***−12.765***−13.028***
Euro-Area−3.005**−3.265−4.830***−4.675***−6.995***−16.790***
Switzerland−3.495***−5.127***−4.704***−12.045***−12.616***−12.760***
qtqt
United Kingdom−2.562−3.471−3.731−5.537***−11.066***−11.305***
Canada−1.750−2.109−2.431−3.549***−9.366***−9.779***
Australia−1.561−2.929−3.140−5.646***−14.709***−13.304***
New Zealand−2.342−3.423−3.164−4.776***−11.665***−6.628***
Sweden−2.739−3.505−4.002**−3.601***−13.746***−14.352***
United States−0.605−3.968−2.650−5.883***−14.439***−13.586***
Japan−1.569−3.716−3.707−3.841***−10.356***−10.539***
Denmark−1.681−4.322−4.837***−3.257**−14.710***−14.780***
Euro-Area−2.331−4.248−2.817−3.135**−12.069***−12.225***
Switzerland−2.708−3.264−3.425−3.881***−11.722***−11.796***

Note(s): * significant at 10% level, ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level

DF-GLS test hypothesis: H0:seriescontainsaunitroot, H1:seriesisstationary, The tests include both a constant and linear trend as both are statistically significant. Zivot-Andrews test hypothesis: H0:seriescontainsaunitroot withabreak, H1:seriesisstationarywithabreak, Tests for a break in both intercept and trend. Lee and Strazicich test hypothesis: H0:seriescontainsaunitroot withbreaks, H1:seriesisstationarywithbreaks, Tests for a break in both intercept and trend

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Constant parameter GMM results for the full sample

r¯φπφyφqSargan test
United KingdomStandard1.7817***1.3449***0.3187**0.2586
(0.1458)(0.2647)(0.1471)
Augmented0.9997***1.1259***0.3089**0.0160***0.4289
(0.0176)(0.2858)(0.1290)(0.0011)
CanadaStandard1.7536***1.6404***0.8117***0.3287
(0.1705)(0.2786)(0.1955)
Augmented5.1436***1.6239***0.3265**−0.03100.7383
(1.1107)(0.2271)(0.1621)(0.0100)
AustraliaStandard1.1849***0.4671***0.5258***0.2053
(0.2116)(0.0916)(0.1879)
Augmented1.6268***0.5487***0.7800***0.5349**0.7975
(0.1150)(0.1151)(0.2571)(0.1901)
New ZealandStandard3.7458***0.7886***0.8215***0.1376
(0.0797)(0.0540)(0.2890)
Augmented1.4981***0.6428***0.4049***−0.0411***0.4302
(0.0799)(0.1156)(0.1406)(0.0087)
SwedenStandard0.7525***1.4415***0.5082**0.1915
(0.1766)(0.3284)(0.2123)
Augmented−0.8318***1.1942***0.2945**0.1441***0.6648
(0.0231)(0.3811)(0.1476)(0.0159)
United StatesStandard1.3516***2.2289***0.50120.6254
(0.1988)(0.4419)(0.3146)
Augmented1.2051***1.6267***0.7833**−0.26210.3776
(0.1821)(0.3626)(0.3412)(0.6842)
JapanStandard0.4518**1.6097***1.1090***0.1039
(0.2183)(0.1336)(0.1685)
Augmented0.4911**1.5800***1.0321***0.09140.2314
(0.2173)(0.1547)(0.1914)(0.1656)
DenmarkStandard0.7385***0.9078***0.05610.1074
(0.0858)(0.0787)(0.1368)
Augmented0.7121***0.9028***0.06750.59010.2607
(0.0876)(0.0979)(0.1366)(0.4862)
Euro-AreaStandard0.8326**1.2938***0.25840.2239
(0.3573)(0.1946)(0.1995)
Augmented−2.03751.0908***0.5412***0.01420.3793
(2.4212)(0.2351)(0.1664)(0.0216)
SwitzerlandStandard2.2613***1.4127***0.4490**0.2548
(0.3257)(0.0772)(0.2271)
Augmented5.8376***1.2209***0.3293**0.0408**0.3418
(1.6809)(0.0965)(0.1376)(0.0200)

Note(s): * significant at 10% level, ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level

Standard errors in parentheses. The regression specification for the standard Taylor rule is that in equation (2), while the specification for the extended Taylor rule is that in equation (3). Overidentification restrictions are tested using the Sargan J-Test with probabilities reported

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Constant parameter GMM results with sub-period comparison with visual break point determination

Sub-periodr¯φπφyφqSargan test
United KingdomStandard1985:1–2009:22.0280***0.4263***0.1127***0.2844
2009:3–2022:120.6623***0.08620.06500.7460
Augmented1985:1–2009:24.6656***0.4702***0.07170.0229***0.5581
2009:3–2022:122.8348*0.23250.1497***0.01900.7193
CanadaStandard1985:1–2009:21.8616***0.6037***0.05090.1620
2009:3–2022:120.6192***0.5930***0.08360.3777
Augmented1985:1–2009:20.50290.5208***0.03210.0118***0.4692
2009:3–2022:124.1342***0.5520***0.02860.0323***0.4857
AustraliaStandard1985:1–2009:22.0076***0.3780***0.2499***0.2052
2009:3–2022:120.7704**1.1906***0.02300.2832
Augmented1985:1–2009:21.8081***0.3838***0.2431***0.06680.2618
2009:3–2022:120.9820**1.2566***0.31530.7365**0.3400
New ZealandStandard1985:1–2009:23.1846***1.0709***0.8930***0.0965
2009:3–2022:122.8008***0.13790.76450.8410
Augmented1985:1–2009:21.24200.4684***0.02400.00880.8885
2009:3–2022:121.76300.05900.45610.00890.5553
SwedenStandard1985:1–2009:21.5008***0.5784***0.05420.1417
2009:3–2022:121.0279***0.20220.10240.2327
Augmented1985:1–2009:21.4921***0.5959***0.09480.4427**0.7223
2009:3–2022:120.48380.28120.02790.20640.6930
United StatesStandard1985:1–2011:121.4947***1.1820***0.18880.4244
2012:1–2022:121.5057***0.5294***0.11430.5105
Augmented1985:1–2011:121.5077***1.0574***0.21210.05370.6010
2012:1–2022:121.7893***0.6971**1.55940.58020.6319
JapanStandard1985:1–2012:120.9308***1.3223***0.4237***0.0997
2013:1–2022:12−2.2996***0.00260.00750.2347
Augmented1985:1–2012:120.8392***1.2815***0.3707***0.06560.2188
2013:1–2022:12−2.5901***0.1751**0.16310.05630.2583
DenmarkStandard1985:1–2011:101.2101***0.3912***0.1010**0.2169
2011:11–2022:12−0.48450.07010.07690.5639
Augmented1985:1–2011:101.2097***0.3874***0.07790.08270.4267
2011:11–2022:12−0.5010**0.08010.07440.18870.8195
Euro-AreaStandard1985:1–2008:92.5416***0.09620.7390***0.1555
2008:10–2022:12−0.20330.4564**0.13920.3102
Augmented1985:1–2008:99.2304***0.41600.6263***0.0526***0.3172
2008:10–2022:12−7.6741***0.21060.04710.0764***0.0590
SwitzerlandStandard1985:1–2008:92.8604***1.2634***0.00920.1672
2008:10–2022:12−0.62780.9355**1.2838**0.6628
Augmented1985:1–2008:91.29311.2275***0.5091***0.02600.7134
2008:10–2022:12−5.7931***0.7538**0.8497**0.1735***0.7452

Note(s): * significant at 10% level, ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level

Standard errors not reported. The regression specification for the standard Taylor rule is that in equation (2), while the specification for the extended Taylor rule is that in equation (3). Overidentification restrictions are tested using the Sargan J-Test with probabilities reported

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Constant parameter GMM results with sub-period comparison using empirical break date determination for the standard Taylor rule

Sub-periodr¯φπφyφqSargan test
United Kingdom1985:1–1993:12.2361***0.2505***0.01610.3343
1993:2–2001:101.8013***0.02710.02500.4445
2001:11–2009:41.4783***0.04780.1779***0.8733
2009:5–2022:120.8402***0.23960.2029***0.4861
Canada1985:1–1993:52.0727***0.2418***0.0572***0.4189
1993:6–2001:121.6320***0.07040.05200.3569
2002:1–2009:51.1086***0.12920.26370.3360
2009:6–2022:12−0.6689***0.5731***0.11240.3437
Australia1985:1–1992:72.3979***0.2384***0.02220.6969
1992:8–2011:101.7043***0.3165***0.2143***0.3558
2011:11–2017:40.8338***0.15040.6367*0.5852
2017:4–2022:12−1.3245***0.8293***0.03610.5963
New Zealand1985:1–1991:112.1463***0.3904***0.05270.5399
1991:12–2009:31.7381***0.1331*0.1232**0.0760
2009:4–2017:60.9488***0.01110.09920.5653
2017:7–2022:120.19240.2911*0.2320*0.6327
Sweden1985:1–1996:102.1032***0.1880***0.06030.5672
1996:11–2009:41.3526***0.04860.02190.4250
2009:5–2017:6−0.9833***0.25180.00100.1134
2017:7–2022:12−5.7824***2.1897***1.3284*0.7922
United States1985:1–2001:121.7526***0.2574***0.05930.0908
2002:1–2009:20.6952***0.2373**0.6969***0.1462
2009:3–2016:2−2.0770***0.0036−0.00040.9965
2016:3–2022:12−0.8103***0.6225***0.24180.2650
Japan1985:1–1995:61.0971***0.2879**0.3257***0.5752
1995:7–2009:9−1.2144***0.5576**0.08990.5790
2009:10–2012:3−3.9960***1.6215***0.08750.8121
2012:4–2022:12−2.3026***0.00000.00000.2623
Denmark1985:1–1994:32.0977***0.1860***0.02490.5701
1994:4–2003:81.0955***0.1659***0.2224***0.5623
2003:9–2009:121.0107***0.1322**0.2122***0.4953
2010:1–2022:12−0.7439***0.25160.12200.8209
Euro-Area1999:1–2009:62.7230***0.10930.6182***0.4114
2009:7–2013:11.0005***0.00030.00030.8913
2013:2–2016:5−0.01150.2219**1.0194***0.7990
2016:6–2022:120.00010.00000.00000.9982
Switzerland1985:1–1995:121.5396***0.2591***0.03260.1991
1996:1–2009:90.1948***0.07860.5147***0.1953
2009:10–2015:3−0.5977***1.2604***0.6325*0.3406
2015:4–2022:12−0.2877***0.00000.00000.9786

Note(s): * significant at 10% level, ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level

Standard errors not reported. The regression specification for the standard Taylor rule is that in equation (2). Overidentification restrictions are tested using the Sargan J-Test with probabilities reported

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Constant parameter GMM results with sub-period comparison using empirical break date determination for the augmented Taylor rule

Sub-periodr¯φπφyφqSargan test
United Kingdom1985:1–1993:12.9018***0.3001***0.0134−0.00590.4372
1993:2–2001:102.5147***0.1140**0.0391−0.0057**0.5931
2001:11–2009:4−0.26440.06300.1707***0.01450.7530
2009:5–2022:12−0.31130.00230.1603***−0.00350.7480
Canada1985:1–1993:5−0.22720.1934***0.02040.0202***0.6209
1993:6–2001:121.4941*0.00680.03980.00110.4572
2002:1–2009:5−0.98720.2320**0.13490.01640.5182
2009:6–2022:12−3.5234**0.5210**0.5010***0.0243*0.5769
Australia1985:1–1992:72.2919***0.2278***0.0457−0.0921**0.8158
1992:8–2011:101.7122***0.1808***0.0837−0.1372***0.3540
2011:11–2017:40.7821***0.16840.6608**0.03620.7133
2017:4–2022:12−1.3385***0.8292***0.03500.03260.7557
New Zealand1985:1–1991:112.2947***0.3261***0.1552**0.1058*0.7625
1991:12–2009:31.7950***0.0853*0.05220.1686***0.1592
2009:4–2017:60.9458***0.00830.1074−0.00140.7792
2017:7–2022:12−0.4877**0.6622***0.0623−0.24800.7766
Sweden1985:1–1996:102.0871***0.1829***0.02010.05370.5195
1996:11–2009:41.3498***0.03400.0200−0.01290.6247
2009:5–2017:6−0.28210.46250.31160.11210.4851
2017:7–2022:12−3.650***0.50403.0061***0.67130.8643
United States1985:1–2001:121.8125***0.1834***0.1110***0.03550.4599
2002:1–2009:20.7984***0.7136***0.6590***0.2326***0.7538
2009:3–2016:2−2.0794***0.00000.00000.00000.9998
2016:3–2022:12−1.3946***0.8223***0.8764***0.3810***0.8687
Japan1985:1–1995:61.0790***0.2615**0.2886***−0.03640.6764
1995:7–2009:9−1.2171***0.6167**0.0800−0.10670.7179
2009:10–2012:3−3.6137***1.1932***0.1305−0.00670.8803
2012:4–2022:12−2.6376***0.6658**0.17070.13930.6200
Denmark1985:1–1994:32.0498***0.1166***0.01260.00930.5842
1994:4–2003:81.1738***0.1147**0.2066***0.09040.6234
2003:9–2009:121.0755***0.1506**0.1675***0.9020***0.7616
2010:1–2022:12−0.7306***0.26430.08820.39580.9627
Euro-Area1999:1–2009:68.4953***0.3843**0.6925***−0.0512***0.5977
2009:7–2013:11.00450.00010.00010.00000.9757
2013:2–2016:50.41060.1705**1.2498***−0.00510.9306
2016:6–2022:120.00010.00000.00000.00000.9315
Switzerland1985:1–1995:121.4153***0.1941***0.0971*−0.05950.3684
1996:1–2009:90.2076***0.02870.5577***−0.16270.1877
2009:10–2015:31.2990*0.95240.30830.24540.8284
2015:4–2022:12−0.2877***0.00000.00000.00000.9909

Note(s): * significant at 10% level, ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level

Standard errors not reported. The regression specification for the augmented Taylor rule is that in equation (3). Overidentification restrictions are tested using the Sargan J-Test with probabilities reported

Source(s): Authors’ own creation

Notes

1.

The sample period includes in the case of inflation targeting countries the point when this monetary regime was adopted and for all countries several periods characterised by economic turbulence and uncertainty (such as the global financial crisis, the Covid-19 pandemic and the Russia–Ukraine conflict).

2.

The exact inflation targets are obtained from the websites of the central banks investigated in this paper.

3.

The filter allows to split output into a trend and a cyclical component.

Appendix

The supplementary material for this article can be found online.

References

Adanur Aklan, N. and Nargelecekenler, M. (2008), “Taylor rule in practice: evidence from Turkey”, International Advances in Economic Research, Vol. 14 No. 2, pp. 156-166, doi: 10.1007/s11294-008-9148-9.

Adolfson, M. (2007), “Incomplete exchange rate pass-through and simple monetary policy rules”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 26 No. 3, pp. 468-494, doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2007.01.005.

Aizenman, J., Hutchison, M. and Noy, I. (2011), “Inflation targeting and real exchange rates in emerging markets”, World Development, Vol. 39 No. 5, pp. 712-724, doi: 10.1016/j.worlddev.2010.11.005.

Alba, J.D. and Wang, P. (2017), “Taylor rule and discretionary regimes in the United States: evidence from a k-state Markov regime-switching model”, Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 21 No. 3, pp. 817-833, doi: 10.1017/s1365100515000693.

Alcidi, C., Flamini, A. and Fracasso, A. (2011), “Policy regime changes, judgment and Taylor rules in the Greenspan era”, Economica, Vol. 78 No. 309, pp. 89-107, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0335.2009.00777.x.

Andrews, D.W. (1993), “Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point”, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, Vol. 61 No. 4, pp. 821-856, doi: 10.2307/2951764.

Batini, N. and Haldane, A. (1998), “Forward-looking rules for monetary policy”, Bank of England, Working Paper No. 91.

Batini, N., Harrison, R. and Millard, S.P. (2003), “Monetary policy rules for an open economy”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 27 Nos 11-12, pp. 2059-2094, doi: 10.1016/s0165-1889(02)00116-1.

Bauer, M.D. and Swanson, E.T. (2023), “A reassessment of monetary policy surprises and high-frequency identification”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 87-155, doi: 10.1086/723574.

Bauer, M.D., Pflueger, C. and Sunderam, A. (2022), “Perceptions about monetary policy”, National Bureau of Economic Research, No. w30480.

Beaudry, P. and Ruge‐Murcia, F. (2017), “Canadian inflation targeting”, Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne D'économique, Vol. 50 No. 5, pp. 1556-1572, doi: 10.1111/caje.12307.

Belke, A.H. and Klose, J. (2009), “Does the ECB rely on a taylor rule?”, in Comparing Ex-Post with Real Time Data, Ruhr Economic Paper, 133.

Bianchi, F., Lettau, M. and Ludvigson, S.C. (2022), “Monetary policy and asset valuation”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 77 No. 2, pp. 967-1017, doi: 10.1111/jofi.13107.

Boivin, J. (2006), “Has US monetary policy changed? Evidence from drifting coefficients and real-time data”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 38 No. 5, pp. 1149-1173, doi: 10.1353/mcb.2006.0065.

Çağlayan, E. and Astar, M. (2010), “Taylor rule: is it an applicable guide for inflation targeting countries”, Journal of Money Investment and Banking, Vol. 18, pp. 55-67.

Caporale, G.M., Helmi, M.H., Çatik, A.N., Ali, F.M. and Akdeniz, C. (2018), “Monetary policy rules in emerging countries: is there an augmented nonlinear TAYLOR rule?”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 72, pp. 306-319, doi: 10.1016/j.econmod.2018.02.006.

Carare, A. and Stone, M.R. (2006), “Inflation targeting regimes”, European Economic Review, Vol. 50 No. 5, pp. 1297-1315, doi: 10.5089/9781451842616.001.

Castro, V. (2011), “Can central banks' monetary policy be described by a linear (augmented) Taylor rule or by a nonlinear rule?”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 7 No. 4, pp. 228-246, doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2010.06.002.

Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (1998), “Monetary policy rules in practice: some international evidence”, European Economic Review, Vol. 42 No. 6, pp. 1033-1067, doi: 10.1016/s0014-2921(98)00016-6.

Clarida, R., Gali, J. and Gertler, M. (2000), “Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115 No. 1, pp. 147-180, doi: 10.1162/003355300554692.

Cochrane, J.H. (2011), “Determinacy and identification with Taylor rules”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 119 No. 3, pp. 565-615, doi: 10.1086/660817.

Conrad, C. and Eife, T.A. (2012), “Explaining inflation-gap persistence by a time-varying Taylor rule”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 34 No. 2, pp. 419-428, doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2012.02.001.

Craven, P. and Wahba, G. (1978), “Smoothing noisy data with spline functions: estimating the correct degree of smoothing by the method of generalized cross-validation”, Numerische Mathematik, Vol. 31 No. 4, pp. 377-403, doi: 10.1007/bf01404567.

Crowley, P.M. and Hudgins, D. (2021), “Is the Taylor rule optimal? Evaluation using a wavelet-based control model”, Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 28 No. 1, pp. 54-60, doi: 10.1080/13504851.2020.1730752.

De Brouwer, G. and Gilbert, J. (2005), “Monetary policy reaction functions in Australia”, Economic Record, Vol. 81 No. 253, pp. 124-134, doi: 10.1111/j.1475-4932.2005.00238.x.

Fendel, R., Frenkel, M. and Rülke, J.C. (2011), “‘Ex-ante’ Taylor rules – newly discovered evidence from the G7 countries”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 33 No. 2, pp. 224-232, doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2010.12.001.

Florens, C., Jondeau, E. and Le Bihan, H. (2001), “Assessing GMM estimates of the federal reserve reaction function”, Banque de France, Working Paper No. 83.

Fregert, K. and Jonung, L. (2008), “Inflation targeting is a success, so far: 100 years of evidence from Swedish wage contracts”, Economics, Vol. 2 No. 1, doi: 10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2008-31.

Gürkaynak, R.S., Kısacıkoğlu, B. and Lee, S.S. (2023), Exchange Rate and Inflation under Weak Monetary Policy: Turkey Verifies Theory, Economic Policy, Online publication ahead of print.

Hudson, K.B. and Vespignani, J. (2018), “Understanding the deviation of Australian policy rate from the Taylor rule”, Applied Economics, Vol. 50 No. 9, pp. 973-989, doi: 10.1080/00036846.2017.1346367.

Judd, J.P. and Rudebusch, G.D. (1998), Taylor's Rule and the Fed: 1970-1997, Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of, San Francisco, pp. 3-16.

Judd, J.P. and Rudebusch, G.D. (2020), “Taylor's rule and the fed: 1970-1997”, in Handbook of Monetary Policy, Routledge, pp. 961-980.

Kendall, R. and Ng, T. (2013), “Estimated Taylor Rules updated for the post-crisis period”, in Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Notes, August 2013.

Kim, C.J. and Nelson, C.R. (2006), “Estimation of a forward-looking monetary policy rule: a time-varying parameter model using ex post data”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 53 No. 8, pp. 1949-1966, doi: 10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.10.017.

Lee, J. and Strazicich, M.C. (2003), “Minimum Lagrange multiplier unit root test with two structural breaks”, Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85 No. 4, pp. 1082-1089, doi: 10.1162/003465303772815961.

Lee, K., Olekalns, N. and Shields, K. (2013), “Meta taylor rules for the UK and Australia”, Accommodating Regime Uncertainty in Monetary Policy Analysis Using Model Averaging Methods, Vol. 81 No. S3, pp. 28-53, The Manchester School, 81, doi: 10.1111/manc.12000.

McCulloch, J.H. (2007), Adaptive Least Squares Estimation of the Time-Varying Taylor Rule, The Ohio State University, Ohio.

Mishkin, F.S. and Schmidt-Hebbel, K. (2001), One decade of inflation targeting in the world: what do we know and what do we need to know?, National Bureau of Economic Research, No. 8397.

Moura, M.L. and de Carvalho, A. (2010), “What can Taylor rules say about monetary policy in Latin America?”, Journal of Macroeconomics, Vol. 32 No. 1, pp. 392-404, doi: 10.1016/j.jmacro.2009.03.002.

Neuenkirch, M. and Tillmann, P. (2014), “Inflation targeting, credibility, and non-linear Taylor rules”, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 41, pp. 30-45, doi: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2013.10.006.

Nikolsko‐Rzhevskyy, A. (2011), “Monetary policy estimation in real time: forward‐looking Taylor rules without forward‐looking data”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 43 No. 5, pp. 871-897, doi: 10.1111/j.1538-4616.2011.00400.x.

Nitschka, T. and Markov, N. (2016), “Semi‐parametric estimates of Taylor rules for a small, open economy–evidence from Switzerland”, German Economic Review, Vol. 17 No. 4, pp. 478-490, doi: 10.1111/geer.12080.

Orphanides, A. (2003), “Historical monetary policy analysis and the Taylor rule”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50 No. 5, pp. 983-1022, doi: 10.1016/s0304-3932(03)00065-5.

Orphanides, A. (2004), “Monetary policy rules, macroeconomic stability, and inflation: a view from the trenches”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 36 No. 2, pp. 151-175, doi: 10.1353/mcb.2004.0013.

Orphanides, A. and Williams, J.C. (2005), “The decline of activist stabilization policy: natural rate misperceptions, learning, and expectations”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 29 No. 11, pp. 1927-1950, doi: 10.17016/ifdp.2004.804.

Österholm, P. (2005), “The Taylor rule: a spurious regression?”, Bulletin of Economic Research, Vol. 57 No. 3, pp. 217-247, doi: 10.1111/j.0307-3378.2005.01220.x.

Papadamou, S., Sidiropoulos, M. and Vidra, A. (2018), “A Taylor Rule for EU members. Does one rule fit to all EU member needs?”, The Journal of Economic Asymmetries, Vol. 18, e00104, doi: 10.1016/j.jeca.2018.e00104.

Partouche, H. (2007), “Time-varying coefficients in a GMM framework: estimation of a forward looking Taylor rule for the Federal Reserve”, Banque de France Working Paper No. 177.

Perruchoud, A. (2009), “Estimating a Taylor rule with Markov switching regimes for Switzerland”, Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 145 No. 2, pp. 187-220, doi: 10.1007/bf03399280.

Razzak, W.A. (2003), “Is the Taylor rule really different from the McCallum rule?”, Contemporary Economic Policy, Vol. 21 No. 4, pp. 445-457, doi: 10.1093/cep/byg024.

Rühl, T.R. (2015), “Taylor rules revisited: ECB and Bundesbank in comparison”, Empirical Economics, Vol. 48 No. 3, pp. 951-967, doi: 10.1007/s00181-014-0820-z.

Sanchez-Robles, B. and Maza, A. (2013), “The European Central Bank monetary policy and the taylor rule, 1999-2009”, Revista de Economía Mundial, No. 33, pp. 179-193, doi: 10.33776/rem.v0i33.4765.

Sargan, J.D. (1958), “The estimation of economic relationships using instrumental variables”, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, Vol. 26 No. 3, pp. 393-415, doi: 10.2307/1907619.

Sauer, S. and Sturm, J.E. (2007), “Using Taylor rules to understand European Central Bank monetary policy”, German Economic Review, Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 375-398, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0475.2007.00413.x.

Sergi, B.S. and Hsing, Y. (2010), “Responses of monetary policy to inflation, the output gap, and real exchange rates: the case of Australia, Canada, and New Zealand”, Global Economy Journal, Vol. 10 No. 2, p. 1850196, doi: 10.2202/1524-5861.1596.

Silva, E.M., Moura, G. and Da Silva, S. (2021), “Monetary policy experiments in an agent-based macroeconomic model”, Open Access Library Journal, Vol. 8 No. 5, pp. 1-14, doi: 10.4236/oalib.1107471.

Sims, C.A. and Zha, T. (2006), “Were there regime switches in US monetary policy?”, American Economic Review, Vol. 96 No. 1, pp. 54-81, doi: 10.1257/000282806776157678.

Sterne, G. (2000), The Use of Inflation Targets in a Global Context, Bank of England, Mimeo.

Stock, J.H. and Watson, M.W. (1998), “Median unbiased estimation of coefficient variance in a time-varying parameter model”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 93 No. 441, pp. 349-358, doi: 10.1080/01621459.1998.10474116.

Svensson, L.E. (2000), “Open-economy inflation targeting”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 50 No. 1, pp. 155-183, doi: 10.1016/s0022-1996(98)00078-6.

Swiss National Bank (2016), Annual Report 1990, Swiss National Bank.

Taylor, J.B. (1993), “Discretion versus policy rules in practice”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39, pp. 195-214, doi: 10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-l.Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy.

Taylor, J. (1998), Monetary Policy and the Long Boom, Federal Reserve Bank Of St. Louis Review, pp. 3-12, Nov.

Taylor, J.B. (1999a), “A historical analysis of monetary policy rules”, in Monetary Policy Rules, University Of Chicago Press, pp. 319-348.

Taylor, J.B. (1999b), “The robustness and efficiency of monetary policy rules as guidelines for interest rate setting by the European Central Bank”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 43 No. 3, pp. 655-679, doi: 10.1016/s0304-3932(99)00008-2.

Taylor, J.B. (2017), “Rules versus discretion: assessing the debate over the conduct of monetary policy, National Bureau of Economic Research, No. 24149.

Taylor, M.P. and Davradakis, E. (2006), “Interest rate setting and inflation targeting: evidence of a nonlinear Taylor rule for the United Kingdom”, Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, Vol. 10 No. 4, doi: 10.2202/1558-3708.1359.

Tiryaki, A., Ceylan, R. and Erdoğan, L. (2018), “Empirical support for augmented taylor rule with asymmetry in selected emerging markets”, Journal of Current Researches on Business and Economics, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 147-164.

Trecroci, C. and Vassalli, M. (2010), “Monetary policy regime shifts: new evidence from time‐varying interest rate rules”, Economic Inquiry, Vol. 48 No. 4, pp. 933-950, doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00222.x.

Woodford, M. (2001), “The Taylor rule and optimal monetary policy”, American Economic Review, Vol. 91 No. 2, pp. 232-237, doi: 10.1257/aer.91.2.232.

Yau, R. (2010), “Estimating forward-looking Taylor rule by GMM with factor instruments”, International Conference On Applied Economics, pp. 837-843.

Yüksel, E., Metin-Ozcan, K. and Hatipoglu, O. (2013), “A survey on time-varying parameter Taylor rule: a model modified with interest rate pass-through”, Economic Systems, Vol. 37 No. 1, pp. 122-134, doi: 10.1016/j.ecosys.2012.08.002.

Zheng, T., Xia, W.A.N.G. and Huiming, G.U.O. (2012), “Estimating forward-looking rules for China's Monetary Policy: a regime-switching perspective”, China Economic Review, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 47-59, doi: 10.1016/j.chieco.2011.07.012.

Zhu, S., Kavanagh, E. and O'Sullivan, N. (2021), “Inflation targeting and financial conditions: UK monetary policy during the great moderation and financial crisis”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 53, 100834, doi: 10.1016/j.jfs.2020.100834.

Zivot, E. and Andrews, D.W.K. (2002), “Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock, and the unit-root hypothesis”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, Vol. 20 No. 1, pp. 25-44, doi: 10.1198/073500102753410372.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to two anonymous referees and to Massimiliano Caporin for helpful comments and suggestions.

Corresponding author

Guglielmo Maria Caporale can be contacted at: guglielmo-maria.caporale@brunel.ac.uk

Related articles