Abstract
Purpose
This research examines the relationship between market power and liquidity creation in the specific context of bank profitability in the Vietnamese banking sector.
Design/methodology/approach
The study applies the methodology proposed by Berger and Bouwman (2009) to demonstrate the creation of bank liquidity through a three-step procedure for investigating the relationship between market power and liquidity creation. The three steps include non-fat liquidity (NFLC), fat liquidity (FLC) and system generalized method of moments estimation for panel data.
Findings
This study finds that liquidity creation increases when a bank has high market power. Further, highly profitable banks positively impact the market power of banks with regard to liquidity creation, relative to less profitable banks. Moreover, bank size, capital, economic growth and interest rate negatively influence bank liquidity creation, while credit risk positively relates to bank liquidity creation.
Research limitations/implications
Measurements used in this study are based on the works of Berger and Bouwman (2009). There are specific variations, relative to Basel III. In addition, other variables significantly impact bank liquidity creation that have not been considered in the models, and a quadratic model should have been considered to measure market power and bank liquidity creation.
Practical implications
This study suggests that managers should control the liquidity of their banks by supervising vulnerable characteristics that have been mentioned herein and emphasizing improvements in profitability. Further, the government may consider encouraging banks to generate more liquidity by modifying regulations concerned with market power or reinforcing policies about improving the transparent business environment.
Originality/value
This study characterizes an attempt to examine the influence of market power on the liquidity creation of banks in Vietnam, which represents one of the most dynamic systems in Asia, with several varied participating banks. The current study also examines the same within the specific context of the modifying impact of the profitability of banks.
Keywords
Citation
Nguyen, T.T.H., Phan, G.Q., Wong, W.-K. and Moslehpour, M. (2023), "The influence of market power on liquidity creation of commercial banks in Vietnam", Journal of Asian Business and Economic Studies, Vol. 30 No. 3, pp. 166-186. https://doi.org/10.1108/JABES-06-2021-0076
Publisher
:Emerald Publishing Limited
Copyright © 2022, Tran Thai Ha Nguyen, Gia Quyen Phan, Wing-Keung Wong and Massoud Moslehpour
License
Published in Journal of Asian Business and Economic Studies. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/legalcode
1. Introduction
The banking sector performs essential functions, such as liquidity creation and risk transformation (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). Banks supply liquidity via liquid liabilities like deposits to finance relatively illiquid assets, such as investments and loans. Thus, banks maintain a balance between the liquidity needs of savers and the demand for long-term financing commitments of corporates (Diamond and Rajan, 2001). By efficiently transforming resources, banks contribute to ensuring the liquidity ability of economic activities. However, the available fund is what ensures the liquidity and access liability to financial resources. As there exists a divergence between assets and liabilities, the capital structure of banks may become more fragile. Consequently, banks fail to generate high liquidity on their balance sheets within a specific period, thereby resulting in adverse outcomes for the economy and increased fragility of the banking sector (Al-Khouri and Arouri, 2019).
Due to the given context, the subject of bank liquidity has greatly appealed to both managers and researchers. Existing literature confirms that the liquidity ability of banks is linked to their market power, from two different perspectives. On the one hand, bank liquidity creation is likely to rise through the "price channel” (Love and Martínez Pería, 2015), which suggests that a high degree of competition may promote credit availability, an idea supported by prior studies such as that of Carbó-Valverde et al. (2009) and Love and Martínez Pería (2012). On the other hand, increased competition can decrease bank profitability, thereby raising bank solvency risk (Jiménez et al., 2013). Thus, under the standards of banking supervision, liquidity is threatened and fragility becomes flagrant. Petersen and Rajan (1995) argued that increased competition reduced liquidity creation, reinforcing the "fragility channel” view. The fragility of the bank is underpinned by its functions in offering protection and transforming maturity to liquidity in order to meet the needs of the creditors (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). In both these mechanisms, the effects of market power in the competitive market are strongly associated with the liquidity creation ability of banks (Davidson et al., 1995).
The Vietnamese banking system is deemed the financial backbone of the economy and is strictly regulated by the State Bank of Vietnam (SBV). Before 1990, it was a one-tier system that did not distinguish between management and commercial functions. The SBV plays both the role of the central bank and the commercial bank. The reform of the banking system in 1990 eliminated the state monopoly and facilitated the diversification of banking activities in terms of ownership and the number of banks. By forming a two-tier banking system, business activities could be separated from functions of state management, operations could be distributed correspondingly across policy and commercial banks and subsidies could be eliminated via interest rates. Following the 2007–09 financial crisis, the SBV implemented a variety of monetary policies to facilitate macroeconomic stability and economic growth. Notably, commercial banks in Vietnam generated the least liquidity in 2011. The ratio of non-fat liquidity creation and fat liquidity creation to total assets was 8.38 and 11.53%, respectively (Figure 1). Since 2012, when SBV loosened the monetary policy, banks began to expand lending and deposit activities. Thus, bank liquidity creation was higher compared to the previous period. Yet, the bank system in Vietnam faces great challenges when its weaknesses have been revealed for a very long time. As the competition among commercial banks continues to worsen, mergers and acquisitions are deemed an indispensable trend. Notably, from 2011 to 2015, there were 8 M&A deals (Appendix). This restructuring of credit institutions' system leads to a change in bank structure and bank market power, thereby raising the question of whether or not the market power affects the liquidity creation decisions of the commercial banks.
This study contributes to the banking literature and practice in certain aspects, with a limited understanding of the bank liquidity creation channel. Firstly, we provide empirical evidence that illustrates the current banking theories on the relationship between market power and liquidity creation of banks. This is carried out with the application of Berger and Bouwman's (2009) calculations to define the degree of liquidity creation across Vietnamese banks and compare it to other countries to confirm the replication of this aforementioned approach to our current study. Secondly, our study examines the influence of market power on liquidity creation among Vietnamese banks in order to make sense of the context of an emerging country. Indeed, Vietnam's financial system has undergone a long reform period, characterized by a disorganized and inefficient banking system and the concentration of power. Jarvis (2002) commented that the main problem before the reform was the poor and unsafe credit provision of the financial institutions in Vietnam. Following the reform in the mid-1980s, the Vietnamese banking system became one of the most dynamic systems in Asia, with varying types of bank participation. This reform significantly changed the price and volume of the offered credit and promotes transparency in the competition among banks. Recently, Dang and Huynh (2022) suggested that the bank lending channel was significantly influenced by the market power and specific factors associated with the banks in Vietnam. Vo and Nguyen (2018) argued that commercial banks, such as Vietcombank and Vietinbank, have the most prominent charter capital in Vietnam and continue contributing capital to the financial market. Therefore, it is imperative to consider the role of market power, as it determines marginal cost shocks translated into the price and volume of borrowed capital (Vanhoose, 1985). To this end, the study offers significant implications for policy-makers and managers of the banking system with regard to providing market liquidity, retaining competitive power and boosting transparency in the market.
This research is organized as follows: Part 2 encompasses the literature review, while Part 3 is concerned with the development of hypotheses. Next, the data and methodology are presented in Part 4. In Part 5, the data set is analyzed and the results are discussed. Finally, Part 6 concludes and offers implications for the commercial bank managers and policy-makers of Vietnam.
2. Literature review
2.1 Ground theories
The liquidity of the bank is defined as its ability to fund the increase in assets and meet its obligations in the short term with few acceptable losses (King, 2013). Banks generate liquidity by converting their liquid assets into illiquid liabilities or by financing their illiquid assets (i.e. investments and loans) with liquid liabilities (i.e. demand deposit) (Berger and Bouwman, 2009). Banks also operate Off-Balance Sheet (OBS) activities, such as loan commitments, to create liquidity (Kashyap et al., 2002). The depositors are provided with available withdrawals for their accounts, while borrowers are committed to long-term cash through loans. Thus, banks maintain a balance between the liquidity needs of savers and the demand for long-term financing commitments, while also contributing capital to the economy (Diamond and Rajan, 2001). Berger and Bouwman (2009) classified all bank assets, liabilities, equity and off-balance sheet activities as liquid, semi-liquid or illiquid; the authors developed a set of indicators to measure liquidity creation by combining the previous classifications in varying ways. In recent years, the measurement of Berger and Bouwman (2009) has been widely used in banking liquidity research (Duan and Niu, 2020; Sahyouni and Wang, 2019).
In this research stream, according to “Relative Market Power” and “Structure – Conduct – Performance” theories, market power significantly affects the behavior of banks via the bank lending and bank risk-taking channel (Lensink and Sterken, 2002; Kahn et al., 2002; Carbó-Valverde et al., 2009; Wang et al., 2022; Nguyen and Phan, 2018b). Competition among commercial banks and high competition (i.e. low market power) were found to influence the pricing policies of banks, thereby diminishing lending rates and increasing deposit rates (Boot and Thakor, 2000). For example, Besanko and Thakor (1992) used an equilibrium analysis to investigate the long-run behavior of banks in the presence of banking deregulation. They demonstrated that enhanced competition among banks led to a drop in equilibrium loan interest rates and increased equilibrium deposit interest rates. Berlin and Mester (1999) found that the US banks operating in a competitive market offered more loan rate smoothing for borrowers. Guzman (2000) analyzed the differences between the economies across competitive and concentrated markets to show that banks in the former environment tended to offer higher deposit rates and lower loan rates than in the latter. Recently, Yang and Shao (2016) used the reverse of the Lerner index to reflect the degree of bank competition, indicating that further competition leads banks to boost more loans by setting lower loan rates to attract new borrowers. They also argued that higher bank competition reduced charter value, which encouraged aggressive lending behavior.
Altunbas et al. (2010) found that an unusually low interest remained over a prolonged period, which increased bank risk-taking. Similarly, Bikker and Vervliet (2018) confirmed that a low-interest-rate environment impaired bank performance and compressed net interest margins. In this context, the bank appeared not to maintain a sufficient number of buffers for risk loans (Kashyap and Stein, 1995). Thus, liquidity creation may rise through the pricing channel (Love and Martínez Pería, 2015). Indeed, banks with sufficient buffer are willing to produce higher liquidity than those with insufficient buffer (Naveed et al., 2017; Jiang et al., 2018).
Moreover, banks with higher liquidity can acquire or merge with weaker ones, collectively aiming to consolidate market power (Al-Khouri and Arouri, 2019). Herein, higher market power will result in more liquidity flowing into the financial market and deficient banks in demand for liquidity. Black and Strahan (2002) outlined empirical evidence to illustrate that deregulation reduced the negative effect of concentration on new incorporations. In other words, the rate of new incorporations improved through a higher bank credit availability, following an increased competition among banks. Kahn et al. (2005) demonstrated that banks with lower competition failed to generate more liquidity, as exemplified by the case study of the US banks. Berger and Hannan (1989) stated that banks with a monopoly power were incentivized to pursue price imposition, creating less liquidity in a poor-competitive market. Likewise, Corvoisier and Gropp (2002) found that European banks operating in a relatively more concentrated market resulted in less liquidity due to lower interest rates being set for the demand deposits.
Previous studies found that bank liquidity creation was positively related to market power. For instance, Joh and Kim (2012) showed that lower bank competition in 25 OCED countries negatively impacted liquidity creation. The authors suggested that banks with lower market power were more conservative in terms of issuing credit and mobilization deposits, leading banks to generate less liquidity. Lei and Song (2013) used annual bank data of China from 1988 to 2009 to report that with the increase in bank market power, Chinese commercial banks create more liquidity. Recently, Toh et al. (2019) claimed that the negative effect of bank competition on liquidity creation disappears for highly diversified banks in Malaysia. However, Lei and Song (2013) confirmed that the market power of banks exerted a negative effect on liquidity creation by utilizing US banks, similar to the study of Horvath et al. (2016) regarding Czech banks. These studies had different conclusions with varying data sets associated with periods, environments and countries. Due to its significant impact on the economy, the influence of market power on the banking sector and bank liquidity requires continuous assessment.
Further, the relationship between liquidity creation, market power and bank profitability remains inconsistent. For example, Berger and Bouwman (2009) analyzed the correlation between liquidity creation and bank profitability of US banks from 1984 to 2014, indicating that for large banks, the relationship remained positive, while for medium and small banks, the association was found to be negative. Moreover, Tran et al. (2016) demonstrated that banks generate low profitability when they create high bank liquidity in the United States from 1996 to 2013. Their work provided the dynamic interrelationships between liquidity creation, regulatory capital and bank performance, based on the vector-autoregression (VAR) and the generalized-method-of-moments (GMM) estimations. This relationship was positive for a lower capitalized bank but negative for a higher capitalized bank, similar to the findings of Le and Pham (2021) for banks in emerging economies between 2012 and 2016. In this context, bank capital and profitability play an interactive role in modifying the relationship between market power and liquidity creation.
2.2 Hypothesis development
Previous literature has confirmed that fierce competition can motivate a down-trend in loans and an up-trend in deposit interests; both boost the increased demand for deposits and loans (Boot and Thakor, 2000). Thus, bank liquidity creation through the “price channel” is expected to increase (Love and Martínez Pería, 2015). In turn, credit availability shall also increase with the competition, as supported by studies authored by Carbó-Valverde et al. (2009) and Love and Martínez Pería (2015). However, increased competition can reduce bank profitability and raise the risk of bank solvency (Jiménez et al., 2013; Horvath et al., 2016). Under the banking supervision's standards, the liquidity is threatened while its fragility remains flagrant. The “fragility channel” view is reinforced by Petersen and Rajan (1995), who argue that increased competition (i.e. low market power) reduces liquidity creation, which justifies the positive relationship between the market power and liquidity creation of banks. The fragility of the bank is underpinned by its function in terms of offering protection and transforming maturity to liquidity in order to meet the needs of the creditors (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). In this context, banks attempt to limit the volume of deposits accepted and reduce the number of loans granted to avoid the threat of bankruptcy and prevent potential risks (Horvath et al., 2016; Moslehpour et al., 2022). As a result, credit allocation and risk management pressures encourage limited liquidity creation (Boyd and De Nicolo, 2005; Peydro et al., 2021).
Simply put, this view argues that a decline in market competition reduces the motivation of banks to seek and establish long-term relationships with new borrowers (Horvath et al., 2016; Abraheem et al., 2020). Consequently, banks with excellent market power (i.e. low competition) stuff more liquidity to the financial market or deficient banks in demand for liquidity, as per the works of Berger et al. (2010), Lei and Song (2013), Horvath et al. (2016) and Jiang et al. (2018). Thus, we investigate whether bank market power improves bank liquidity creation in this context. Our hypothesis is as follows:
Banks with higher market power generate higher liquidity.
Although some studies focus on bank liquidity, a limited number of them emphasize the role of bank performance or profitability. For example, Berger and Bouwman (2009) find that banks may increase the amount of net surplus distributed to stakeholders by creating more liquidity, thereby enhancing the value of the bank (Sahyouni and Wang, 2019). Meanwhile, Bordeleau and Graham (2010) and Sahyouni and Wang (2019) showed that banks could reduce the risk of illiquidity and default by holding more liquid assets. Al-Khouri and Arouri (2019) emphasized that bank profitability could transfer funds by generating more loans and investments; high market power increased bank profitability and the capacity of banks to offer liquidity. Thus, their findings linked profitability, market power and liquidity of banks.
Furthermore, Toh et al. (2019) found that the liquidity generation capacity of banks declined along with market power; yet, a “buffer” through which banks could guarantee operations would enhance their resilience and create liquidity in the event of such a decline. As there is a sufficient buffer in place, more profitable banks are willing to take on higher risks and create more liquidity than less profitable banks (Hellmann et al., 2000). Thus, the profitable ability is crucial in associating the market power and liquidity creation of banks. Previous studies also demonstrated a variation in the liquidity-profitability between large and small banks, as well as high-capitalized and low-capitalized banks (Berger and Bouwman, 2009; Tran et al., 2016; Le and Pham, 2021). For this study, we outline the second hypothesis, to test the role of profitability in the relationship between market power and liquidity creation, as follows:
The market power of highly profitable banks impacts their liquidity creation.
3. Data and research model
3.1 Sample selection
The structure of the Vietnamese banking sector encompasses four groups: state-owned banks, private joint-stock commercial banks, branches of foreign banks and foreign joint-venture banks. As this study solely focuses on domestic banks, it does not incorporate branches of foreign banks. Therefore, we have selected 32 commercial banks operating in Vietnam from 2010 to 2018. Our criteria required banks to provide sufficient data regarding the annual financial statements during the research period. Secondly, the banks in this study were either acquired or controlled under special terms by the State Bank of Vietnam, following the recommendations of prior studies (e.g. Nguyen and Phan, 2018a; Nguyen and Phan, 2018b). This study also eliminates the merged and consolidated banks operating during this period. Based on these criteria, our sample consists of 24 commercial banks, including 3 state-owned commercial banks and 21 private commercial banks. Private banks are those wherein more than 50% of the total shares are owned by a private party, who may be a foreign partner as well. The final sample includes 238 observations of OBS activities for 24 banks. Finally, macro-economic data, such as GDP growth and interest rates, were collected from the World Development Indicators (WDI) and the International Monetary Fund (IMF).
3.2 Variable measurement
3.2.1 Bank liquidity creation
Berger and Bouwman (2009) propose two measures to create bank liquidity through a three-step procedure, including non-fat liquidity (NFLC), which contains only on-balance sheet activities, and fat liquidity (FLC), which considers both on-balance sheet and OBS activities, which create liquidity similar to on-balance sheet liquidity.
Firstly, the categories of liquid, semi-liquid and illiquid are determined based on assets, liabilities, equity and OBS activities. Following the method of Berger and Bouwman (2009), this research classifies the same into varying categories, as shown in Table 1. Due to the ease, cost and timeliness with which banks employ their liquid fund to support their commitments, it is believed that category-based classifications would be more appropriate than maturity-based; further, it would be more relevant than the time to self-liquidation. Secondly, the activities of a bank are associated with varying weights according to liquidity creation intuition, the magnitudes of which are determined based on the following assessments: a unit of liquidity is created by converting a unit of liquid liabilities into that of illiquid OBS activities or illiquid assets. However, a unit of liquidity is destroyed by converting a unit of illiquid liabilities or equity into that of liquid OBS activities or liquid assets. Following the works of Berger and Bouwman (2009), a weight of 0.5 is allocated for illiquid OBS activities, illiquid assets and liquid liabilities, whereas a weight of 0.0 is proposed for semi-liquid OBS, semi-liquid assets and semi-liquid liabilities. Thus, a weight of −0.5 is assigned for liquid OBS activities, liquid assets and illiquid liabilities. Thirdly, FC and NFC are calculated by combining the activities as determined and weighted in equation (1) and equation (2), respectively.
3.2.2 Market power
The Lerner index, a standard of market power used in banking studies, has been used. The difference between the output price, P and the marginal cost relative to the price of MC (Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga, 2010) is divided by P to obtain the Lerner index, which is demonstrated in the following equation:
Equation (4) indicates that MC is a function of Cost and output products Q, wherein the bank cost Cost is a function of output:
3.2.3 Control variables
Based on the recommendations from the previous studies, the current work of research selected other variables to control for firm-specific characteristics and macroeconomic conditions that may be associated with the creation of bank liquidity. These are bank size (SIZE) at year-end, which is using the natural logarithm of the book value of total assets (Distinguin et al., 2013; Berger et al., 2016; Casu et al., 2018); bank capital (CAP), which is the ratio between equity and total assets at year-end (Diamond and Rajan, 2001), and credit risk (NPL), calculated by the proportion of non-performing loans to total loans at the year-end (Berger and Bouwman, 2009; Horvath et al., 2016). Moreover, the macro-variables adopted in this study are economic growth (GDPGR), which is measured as the annual changes in the gross domestic product (Athanasoglou et al., 2008; Rauch et al., 2010), and interest rate (RATE), which is the monetary policy-related interest rate of the economy, collected from the reports of Vietnam State Bank, as suggested by Casu et al. (2018) and Nguyen and Phan (2018b). Furthermore, we use the re-finance rate, as suggested by IMF, to measure the monetary policy-related interest rate of the economy. As previously mentioned, Yeddou and Pourroy (2020) suggested that ownership structure may contribute to the relationship with bank liquidity. However, this study believes that Vietnam also depends on a banking system that acts as the financial backbone of the economy, which passed the history of the centrally planned economy with the dominance of state-owned banks. Although state ownership has significantly declined since equitization from the 1986 reform, both state-owned and non-state banks believe that they represent the “tactful tool” of the government in the implementation of monetary policies to achieve stability in the macro-economy, curb inflation and ensure the social security of the country. Therefore, we temporarily disregard state ownership in this research; it may be considered separately in subsequent studies.
3.3 Research model
We develop the models used by Rauch et al. (2010) and Casu et al. (2018) to investigate the influence of market power on bank liquidity creation in Vietnam:
Although the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) is also a measure of market concentration, calculated by squaring the market share of each competing entity in a market and then summing the resulting numbers (Ali et al., 2021), with a range between 0 and 10,000, each entity can have up to the bulk of its business for a particular market segment. For example, this problem can occur when an industry entity has roughly equal market shares, but each operates only in specific areas; they will have a monopoly in that particular market. Thus, for HHI to be adequately used, other factors must be considered, and the market must be clearly defined.
Meanwhile, the Lerner index measures the market power of a bank, which is set between the price of a commodity and its marginal cost (Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga, 2010). The higher the value of the Lerner index, the more likely the entity will charge higher marginal costs. Hence, the more significant its monopoly power would be. The Lerner index better reflects monopoly power. For example, Repkova (2012) estimated the market power in the Czech banking industry between 2000 and 2010. He found that HHI showed a trend of modest decrease, indicating that market concentration changed appreciably over the sample period. However, the Lerner index showed that the Czech banking sector operated between two extremes: monopoly and perfect competition, and the estimated level of competition in the Czech deposit market was based on period. Thus, this study used the Lerner index to measure the market power of a bank. Other variables of equation (6) have been defined in Section 4.2.
Further, the study intends to determine if the profitability level of a bank alters the relationship between bank liquidity creation and market power by employing an interactive term of market power and profitability level –
Notably, equations (6) and (7) represent dynamic models with a lagged factor of the dependent variable, which may cause endogenous problems. In this case, endogeneity can be inconsistent and biased (Ullah et al., 2018). The GMM method, according to Arellano and Bover (1995), is suitable for dealing with endogeneity as it eliminates unobserved effects and allows the creation of orthogonal conditions between
4. Result and discussions
Table 2 illustrates the variables encompassed by the descriptive statistics of the study, such as liquidity creation, Lerner index, bank size, bank capital, credit risk, economic growth and interest rate. The abbreviations of these variables are shown in Section 4. The mean values of FLC and NFLC received 10.3216 and 7.9603%, respectively. FLC and NFLC range from a minimum of −17.9559% and −18.3960% to the maximum values of 41.2741 and 30.6165%, respectively. Correspondingly, Petrolimex Group Commercial Joint Stock Bank and Tien Phong Commercial Joint Stock Bank create the most and least liquidity. Moreover, this average liquidity creation appears to be much lower than in other countries, including developed and developing countries. For example, this ratio is smaller than the 17% in Malaysia (Toh et al., 2019), the 20% in the Czech Republic (Horvath et al., 2016) and the 22–30% in the United States (Jiang et al., 2018). An explanation for the lower level of liquidity creation in Vietnamese banks is that bank size is smallest compared to other countries, leading to a decrease in the generation of liquidity.
LERNER has a mean value of 0.220,054 in our sample, with a standard deviation of 0.100,453. Thus, it is lower in comparison with China (about 0.3914) or Singapore (about 0.3316) (Fu et al., 2015), indicating that rivalry among commercial banks was rather aggressive from 2010 through 2018. Specifically, the lowest LERNER is 0.0000 (Tien Phong Commercial Joint Stock Bank), while the highest is 0.493945 (The Vietnam Technological and Commercial Joint Stock Bank).
We present the correlation matrix in Table 3. Based on these results, market power, bank size, credit risk and economic growth were found to positively correlate with liquidity creation. In contrast, equity and interest rates negatively correlate with liquidity creation. The correlation coefficients of the independent variables are all less than 0.8.
Table 3 shows the estimation results of the impact of market power on bank liquidity creation in Vietnam. According to Kiviet (2020), the p-value of the AR(1) test is often less than 10% in default, while the p-values of the AR(2) test have to be greater than 10%, indicating the lack of autocorrelation problems. Similarly, the Hansen test shows that the instruments, as a group, are exogenous, which confirms that GMM estimations are appropriately conducted, and the estimated findings are reliable and unbiased.
We confirm that the liquidity creation of banks is attached to lagged liquidity creation. This implies that liquidity creation is a series of continuous activities that relate to banks over time. Our model eliminates the continuous influence of liquidity creation over time to ensure that the impact of the remaining factors can be more clearly depicted. We find that LERNER positively correlates with bank liquidity creation at a 1% significance level across the regressions. The empirical results indicate that banks with higher market power create more liquidity than those with lower market power, including FLC and NFLC measurements in Table 4. A greater market power increases liquidity creation by 1.4364 and 0.8670 points for FLC and NFLC with a 1% significant statistic, respectively. This result supports our hypothesis that banks with higher market power will generate higher liquidity, consistent with the “fragility channel” view and prior empirical studies such as Berger et al. (2010), Joh and Kim (2012), Lei and Song (2013), Horvath et al. (2016) and Jiang et al. (2018). The above explanations emphasize that increased competition reinforces financing impediments and lending rates, thereby increasing bank fragility. Thus, banks with low competition have to reduce their profits and increase their liquidity buffer to prevent risks and losses. These results support the prediction that the ability of a bank to create liquidity depends on the ability of bank competition. Our view is that a low degree of market power encourages the customer to switch banks and challenges banks in their ability to offset the costs of building long-run relationships with customers (Petersen and Rajan, 1995; Degryse and Ongena, 2005; Leroy and Lucotte, 2017). Thus, we note that commercial banks in Vietnam that transformed from state-owned banks should significantly enhance the competitive power to increase credit supply.
The regression results show a negative and significant relationship among SIZE, FLC and NFLC. The finding suggests that larger banks will create less liquidity than smaller ones, which is consistent with the findings of Berger and Bouwman (2009), Fu et al. (2015) and Le (2019), who claimed the existence of a negative link between liquidity creation and bank capital. However, these studies only consider bank capital as a significant factor of bank power, while our study uses the LERNER index to cover all factors of the market power of the bank, including output price and the marginal cost. Fu et al. (2015) also suggested that this relationship varied by bank size and region, implying that the relationship between market power and liquidity creation may differ in each country. In addition, bank capital significantly and negatively influences bank liquidity creation at a 10% level. Diamond and Rajan (2001) and Le (2019) argue that banks with a higher capital decrease customer deposits (crowd-out), and, as a result, banks produce less liquidity. Finally, credit risk positively impacts bank liquidity creation at a 1% significance level across the regressions, characterizing a positive relationship between liquidity risk and credit risk in prior studies (He and Xiong, 2012; Imbierowicz and Rauch, 2014). Notably, our results contrast that of Le and Pham (2021), who argued that credit risk negatively impacted liquidity creation. We note that there are differences in these studies in terms of the period time. However, it raises the question of whether or not there exists a threshold of credit risk in liquidity creation, which may be addressed in subsequent studies.
Economic growth shows a significant negative relationship with bank liquidity creation in terms of macroeconomics variables. Economic growth improves borrowers' income and payment capacity, which compels borrowers to prepay loans, thereby reducing bank lending. As a result, bank liquidity creation decreases. The interest rate also shows a significant adverse effect on bank liquidity creation. The tight monetary policy will decrease the liquidity created by commercial banks. Casu et al. (2018) suggest that commercial banks raise the price of loans and the deposit rate when the interest rate of the economy increases. This phenomenon impedes the demand of households and firms for credit and deposits, thus reducing bank liquidity creation.
Table 5 illustrates the estimated results of the impact of market power on bank liquidity creation by bank profitability. Firstly, we observe that the Lerner index positively correlates with bank liquidity creation at a 1% significance level in all regression models. It indicates that banks with higher market power create more liquidity than ones with lower market power. Secondly, the coefficient β on
Since banks must satisfy the regulatory capital framework, they attempt to seek profitability to build capital (Blum, 1999; Perotti et al., 2011). When more profit is generated, banks improve their income-generating capacity and operating synergy (Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga, 2010). As a result, the impact of market power on liquidity creation is more substantial in the higher profitability banks, compared to lower profitability banks.
To verify the robustness of the findings, we further investigate the impact of market power on bank liquidity creation using alternative liquidity creation measures, NFCL_EX and FLC_EX. According to liquidity creation theories, banks produce more liquidity by transforming illiquid assets into liquid liabilities than illiquid claims such as equity (Fu et al., 2015). To address this potential concern, Berger and Bouwman (2009) suggested that equity should be detached from basic measures. Hence, two alternative measures, FLC_EX (fat liquidity creation but excluding equity) and NFLC_EX (non-fat liquidity creation but excluding equity), are employed in this study. Table 4 demonstrates the impacts of market power on bank liquidity creation in two alternative measures. The empirical results suggest that our hypotheses also consist of both NFLC with FLC and NFLC_EX with FLC_EX measures. Consequently, a high bank market power level leads to increased liquidity creation. Furthermore, highly profitable banks positively impact their market power on liquidity creation, relative to less profitable banks (see Table 6).
5. Conclusion
Our study assesses the effect of market power on the liquidity creation of Vietnamese commercial banks from 2010 to 2018. Applying the GMM estimation, our study finds that market power, measured using the Lerner index, significantly impacts bank liquidity creation. The empirical findings show that bank liquidity increases when a bank has high market power, and the converse is correct as well. These results support the “fragility channel” view, in which lending rates and financing impediments are pushed by the increased competition, leading to increased bank fragility. In other words, a bank with lower market power has a higher level of risk-aversion and supplies a lower liquidity creation. The financial market is believed to react differently to the competition between emerging and developed countries. However, our main results remain robust as per several robustness tests, confirming that bank market power matters for liquidity creation in the financial market. In the further step, this study determines whether the profitability of the bank played a role in the relationship between market power and liquidation. This study also finds that highly profitable banks positively market power in terms of liquidity creation than less profitable banks. As previous studies did not fully claim the role of bank profitability in liquidity creation, our study indicates that profitability is determined as a “buffer” in creating high liquidity, especially in the context of declined market power.
As side effects, our study finds that bank capital decreases liquidity creation, demonstrating the support for the “financial fragility.” The study also finds that interest and economic growth negatively impact the bank's ability to provide liquidity. The increased borrowing needs in the growing economy have placed banks in advance overloading, resulting in decreased liquidity creation. Our results also show a significantly negative influence of interest, demonstrating that tight monetary policy causes adverse effects on creating liquidity. By contrast, credit risk positively impacts bank liquidity creation, denoting a positive relationship between liquidity creation and liquidity risk, due to a high risk-taking appetite.
Our findings have some implications for managers of banks and policy-makers of government. Firstly, managers should control their bank's liquidity by supervising vulnerable characteristics mentioned in this study, which include risk-taking appetite and the capital ability of a bank to achieve liquidity creation quickly. Managers must balance the advantages and disadvantages of liquidity creation and consider the competitiveness of the bank before making decisions. Secondly, our study supports the expansionary monetary policy that maintains interest rates low enough to boost the liquidity creation of banks. Finally, the government should encourage banks to create more liquidity by changing regulations concerning controlled market power to promote investment, especially in the growing economy. Regulations may be reinforced regarding liquidity and a transparent business environment may be created to prevent the risk-taking appetite and avoid liquidity risk. Finally, the increased competitiveness through the application of technology to provide deposit and lending services is an urgent implication for enhancing the bank's ability to create liquidity.
However, our research also has some limitations. Firstly, the liquidity measurement in this study is based on the work of Berger and Bouwman (2009), and there are specific differences compared to Basel III. However, future studies are necessary due to the uncertainty in the definition and measurement of liquidity. Furthermore, this study does not address the causality between market power and liquidity creation of banks, although some suggestions raised this question in their studies (Davidson et al., 1995). Besides, the limitation of data is also an issue to consider. Although the current study was conducted using data from banks listed in Vietnam and other particular banks excluded from the statistical sample due to their specific nature, this result may not be generalized to all commercial banks. Finally, other variables can significantly impact bank liquidity creation and are not integrated into our models, such as state ownership (Nguyen and Wong, 2021) and business environment (Nguyen et al., 2020). Therefore, a quadratic model should have been considered to measure market power and bank liquidity creation in follow-up studies.
Figures
Liquidity classification of bank activities
Assets | ||
---|---|---|
Illiquid assets (weight = 0.5) | Semi-liquid assets (weight = 0) | Liquid assets (weight = −0.5) |
Commercial and corporate loans | Consumer/Retail loans | Deposits and loans to other credit institutions |
Other loans | Loans and advances to banks | Trading securities |
Fixed assets | Investment securities | |
Other assets | Derivatives | |
Long-term investment |
Liabilities plus equity | ||
---|---|---|
Liquid liabilities (weight = 0.5) | Semi-liquid liabilities (weight = 0) | Illiquid liabilities plus equity (weight = −0.5) |
Customer deposits-current | Customer deposits – term | Senior debt maturing after one year |
Customer deposits-saving | Term deposits from banks | Subordinated borrowing |
Demand deposits from banks and other credit institutions | Other deposits | Other funding |
Short-term borrowing from banks | Other liabilities | |
Certificates of deposit | Total equity |
OBS activities | ||
---|---|---|
Illiquid O.B.S. (weight = 0.5) | Semi-liquid O.B.S. (weight = 0) | Liquid O.B.S. (weight = −0.5) |
Acceptances and documentary credits reported OBS | Guarantees | |
Committed credit lines | ||
Other contingent liabilities |
Source(s): Berger and Bouwman (2009) and Fu et al. (2015)
Descriptive statistics for all variables
Variable | Mean | Sd | Min | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|
NFLC (%) | 7.9603 | 9.3967 | −18.3960 | 30.6165 |
FLC (%) | 10.3216 | 10.7801 | −17.9559 | 41.2741 |
NFLC_EX (%) | 12.6041 | 9.1207 | −8.8753 | 37.2515 |
FLC_EX (%) | 14.9654 | 10.5542 | −7.7528 | 47.9091 |
LERNER | 0.220054 | 0.100453 | 0.0000 | 0.493945 |
CAP (%) | 9.2875 | 4.1620 | 4.0618 | 25.6425 |
SIZE (LOG) | 32.3269 | 1.1773 | 30.1630 | 34.8111 |
NPL (%) | 1.2942 | 0.9051 | 0.0046 | 6.0427 |
GDPGR (%) | 6.2327 | 0.5761 | 5.2474 | 7.0758 |
RATE (%) | 6.4333 | 2.9889 | 3.6639 | 13.1457 |
Source(s): Authors
Correlation matrix
NFLC | FLC | NFLC_EX | FLC_EX | LERNER | CAP | SIZE | NPL | GDPGR | RATE | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NFLC | 1 | |||||||||
FLC | 0.9328*** | 1 | ||||||||
NFLC_EX | 0.9752*** | 0.9145*** | 1 | |||||||
FLC_EX | 0.9052*** | 0.9812*** | 0.93*** | 1 | ||||||
LERNER | 0.146** | 0.2911*** | 0.1038 | 0.257*** | 1 | |||||
CAP | −0.2415*** | −0.2039*** | −0.0206 | −0.0111 | −0.2047*** | 1 | ||||
SIZE | 0.2751*** | 0.3095*** | 0.1207* | 0.1755*** | 0.6608*** | −0.713*** | 1 | |||
NPL | 0.2344*** | 0.2093*** | 0.2637*** | 0.233*** | −0.0548 | 0.0973 | 0.0518 | 1 | ||
GDPGR | 0.1448** | 0.1395** | 0.1008 | 0.1007 | 0.2664*** | −0.212*** | 0.1808*** | −0.2681*** | 1 | |
RATE | −0.1884*** | −0.1587** | −0.1419** | −0.117* | −0.1163* | 0.2289*** | −0.2053*** | 0.1502** | −0.6207*** | 1 |
Note(s): significance level (***p < 1%)
Source(s): Authors
The effect of market power on bank liquidity creation: baseline model
Dependent variable | Fat liquidity creation (FLC) | Non-fat liquidity creation (NFLC) |
---|---|---|
Lag of FLC | 0.3706*** | |
(5.16) | ||
Lag of NFLC | 0.1685*** | |
(3.90) | ||
LERNER | 1.4364*** | 0.8670*** |
(3.29) | (6.08) | |
CAP | −1.6866** | −1.4528*** |
(−2.11) | (−4.36) | |
SIZE | −7.0879 | −4.2347* |
(−1.12) | (−1.79) | |
NPL | 2.6527*** | 3.0471*** |
(3.49) | (4.87) | |
GDPGR | −4.9699*** | −2.6263*** |
(−4.14) | (−3.51) | |
RATE | −0.4003*** | −0.2681* |
(−2.62) | (−1.89) | |
Constant | 250.8444 | 152.6170** |
(1.22) | (2.00) | |
Observations | 192 | 192 |
Number of groups | 24 | 24 |
Number of IVs | 20 | 20 |
AR(1) (p-value) | 0.0142 | 0.0611 |
AR(2) (p-value) | 0.1685 | 0.1535 |
Hansen (p-value) | 0.1950 | 0.1129 |
Note(s): significance level (***p < 1%), (**p < 5%), (*p < 10%) and ( ) is t-statistic
Source(s): Authors
The effect of market power on bank liquidity creation by bank profitability level
Dependent variable | Fat liquidity creation (FLC) | Non-fat liquidity creation (NFLC) |
---|---|---|
Lag of FLC | 0.2820*** | |
(6.36) | ||
Lag of NFLC | 0.2053*** | |
(2.69) | ||
LERNER | 0.4371** | 0.7560*** |
(1.96) | (2.62) | |
LERNER*D_HIGH | 0.1559** | 0.1558* |
(2.19) | (1.73) | |
CAP | −1.3197*** | −1.6122*** |
(−4.00) | (−3.81) | |
SIZE | −6.9548*** | −6.6564** |
(−2.74) | (−2.23) | |
NPL | 1.9913*** | 1.8154*** |
(4.48) | (3.92) | |
GDPGR | 0.5060 | −1.9382* |
(0.65) | (−1.91) | |
RATE | −0.1250 | −0.1797 |
(−1.00) | (−1.45) | |
Constant | 228.9966*** | 229.7151** |
(2.85) | (2.33) | |
Observations | 192 | 192 |
Number of groups | 24 | 24 |
Number of IVs | 24 | 23 |
AR(1) (p-value) | 0.0153 | 0.0321 |
AR(2) (p-value) | 0.2924 | 0.4185 |
Hansen (p-value) | 0.1586 | 0.1627 |
Note(s): significance level (***p < 1%), (**p < 5%), (*p < 10%) and ( ) is t-statistic
Source(s): Authors
The effect of market power on bank liquidity creation: robustness check
Dependent variable | FLC_EX | NFLC_EX | FLC_EX | NFLC_EX |
---|---|---|---|---|
Lag of FLC_EX | 0.3007*** | 0.2160*** | ||
(7.40) | (2.86) | |||
Lag of NFLC_EX | 0.1483*** | 0.1823** | ||
(3.66) | (2.52) | |||
LERNER | 1.1742*** | 0.8667*** | 0.7773* | 0.6822*** |
(3.96) | (6.90) | (1.72) | (2.61) | |
LERNER*D_HIGH | 0.2541* | 0.1626* | ||
(1.76) | (1.86) | |||
CAP | −0.9400** | −0.9430*** | −1.1455** | −1.0957*** |
(−2.34) | (−2.82) | (−2.10) | (−2.58) | |
SIZE | −6.4829* | −4.2435** | −6.1679* | −6.1008** |
(−1.82) | (−1.98) | (−1.71) | (−2.17) | |
NPL | 1.7862*** | 3.1499*** | 3.5232*** | 1.8676*** |
(2.80) | (5.03) | (5.56) | (3.94) | |
GDPGR | −3.5547*** | −2.3613*** | −0.5782 | −1.4258 |
(−4.34) | (−3.21) | (−0.75) | (−1.63) | |
RATE | −0.2630* | −0.2774** | −0.0087 | −0.1292 |
(−1.86) | (−2.41) | (−0.05) | (−1.23) | |
Constant | 225.5925** | 150.9183** | 201.2365* | 208.9827** |
(1.97) | (2.16) | (1.75) | (2.26) | |
Observations | 192 | 192 | 192 | 192 |
Groups | 24 | 24 | 24 | 24 |
Instruments | 24 | 21 | 24 | 23 |
AR(1) (p-value) | 0.0250 | 0.0621 | 0.0295 | 0.0353 |
AR(2) (p-value) | 0.1287 | 0.1487 | 0.2179 | 0.4038 |
Hansen (p-value) | 0.2352 | 0.1499 | 0.2261 | 0.1473 |
Note(s): significance level (***p < 1%), (**p < 5%), (*p < 10%) and ( ) is t-statistic
Source: Authors
Year | Target banks or financial institutions | Acquirer banks |
---|---|---|
2011 | Saigon Commercial Bank | Saigon Commercial Bank |
Tin Nghia Bank | ||
First Commercial Bank | ||
2012 | HabuBank | Saigon Hanoi Bank |
2013 | Dai A Bank | HoChiMinh City Development Bank |
2013 | Western Bank | Public Commercial Bank |
PetroVietnam Finance Corporation | ||
2015 | Vietnam Construction Bank | SBV |
Ocean Bank | ||
GP Bank | ||
2015 | Mekong Housing Bank | BIDV |
2015 | Mekong Development Bank | Maritime Bank |
2015 | Southern Bank | Sacombank |
Note
Market power can be measured from the perspective of NEIO and IO. However, among these measures, Lerner can reflect the change in market power among banks over time, while other indexes fail to do so.
Funding: This research received no external funding.
Conflicts of interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.
Appendix Mergers and acquisitions in the period 2010–2018
References
Abraheem, N., Yahya, M.H., Muhamma, J. and Razak, N.H.A. (2020), “Liquidity creation and competition in the banking industry pre and post Arab spring in Mena region”, Academy of Accounting and Financial Studies Journal, Vol. 24 No. 1, pp. 1-12.
Agustini, M. and Viverita, V. (2012), “Factors influencing the profitability of listed Indonesian commercial banks before and during financial global crisis”, Indonesian Capital Market Review, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 29-40.
Al-Khouri, R. and Arouri, H. (2019), “Market power and the role of banks as liquidity providers in gcc markets”, Cogent Economics and Finance, Vol. 7 No. 1, 1639878.
Ali, M., Haroon, O., Rizvi, S.a.R. and Azmi, W. (2021), “Stability versus fragility: new evidence from 84 banks”, Studies in Economics and Finance, Vol. 38 No. 2, pp. 441-453.
Altunbas, Y., Gambacorta, L. and Marques-Ibanez, D. (2010), “Bank risk and monetary policy”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 6 No. 3, pp. 121-129.
Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1995), “Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models”, Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 68 No. 1, pp. 29-51.
Athanasoglou, P.P., Brissimis, S.N. and Delis, M.D. (2008), “Bank-specific, industry-specific and macroeconomic determinants of bank profitability”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, Vol. 18 No. 2, pp. 121-136.
Berger, A.N. and Bouwman, C.H.S. (2009), “Bank liquidity creation”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 22 No. 9, pp. 3779-3837.
Berger, A.N. and Hannan, T.H. (1989), “The price-concentration relationship in banking”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71 No. 2, p. 291.
Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H.S., Kick, T.K. and Schaeck, K. (2010), “Bank liquidity creation and risk taking during distress”, SSRN Electronic Journal, available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1567573 (accessed 20 March 2022).
Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H., Kick, T. and Schaeck, K. (2016), “Bank liquidity creation following regulatory interventions and capital support”, Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 26, pp. 115-141.
Berlin, M. and Mester, L.J. (1999), “Deposits and relationship lending”, Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 12 No. 3, pp. 579-607.
Besanko, D. and Thakor, A.V. (1992), “Banking deregulation: allocational consequences of relaxing entry barriers”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 16 No. 5, pp. 909-932.
Bikker, J.A. and Vervliet, T.M. (2018), “Bank Profitability and risk-taking under low interest rates”, International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 3-18.
Black, S.E. and Strahan, P.E. (2002), “Entrepreneurship and bank credit availability”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 57 No. 6, pp. 2807-2833.
Blum, J. (1999), “Do capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking?”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 23 No. 5, pp. 755-771.
Boot, A.W.A. and Thakor, A.V. (2000), “Can relationship banking survive competition?”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 55 No. 2, pp. 679-713.
Bordeleau, É. and Graham, C. (2010), The Impact of Liquidity on Bank Profitability, Bank of Canada, Ottawa.
Boyd, J.H. and De Nicolo, G. (2005), “The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 60 No. 3, pp. 1329-1343.
Carbó-Valverde, S., Rodríguez-Fernández, F. and Udell, G.F. (2009), “Bank Market power and sme financing constraints”, Review of Finance, Vol. 13 No. 2, pp. 309-340.
Casu, B., Di Pietro, F. and Trujillo-Ponce, A. (2018), “Liquidity creation and bank capital”, Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 56 No. 3, pp. 307-340.
Corvoisier, S. and Gropp, R. (2002), “Bank concentration and retail interest rates”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 26 No. 11, pp. 2155-2189.
Dang, V.D. and Huynh, J. (2022), “Bank funding, market power, and the bank liquidity creation channel of monetary policy”, Research in International Business and Finance, Vol. 59, 101531.
Davidson, J., Davidson, R. and Mackinnon, J.G. (1995), “Estimation and inference in econometrics”, Economica, Vol. 62 No. 245, p. 133.
Degryse, H. and Ongena, S. (2005), “Distance, lending relationships, and competition”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 60 No. 1, pp. 231-266.
Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Huizinga, H. (2010), “Bank activity and funding strategies: the impact on risk and returns”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 98 No. 3, pp. 626-650.
Diamond, D.W. and Dybvig, P.H. (1983), “Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91 No. 3, pp. 401-419.
Diamond, D.W. and Rajan, R.G. (2001), “Liquidity risk, liquidity creation, and financial fragility: a theory of banking”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 109 No. 2, pp. 287-327.
Distinguin, I., Roulet, C. and Tarazi, A. (2013), “Bank regulatory capital and liquidity: evidence from us and European publicly traded banks”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 37 No. 9, pp. 3295-3317.
Duan, Y. and Niu, J. (2020), “Liquidity creation and bank profitability”, The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, Vol. 54, 101250.
Fu, X.M., Lin, Y.R. and Molyneux, P. (2015), “Bank liquidity creation and regulatory capital in Asia pacific”, in Bank Competition, Efficiency and Liquidity Creation in Asia Pacific, Palgrave Macmillan Studies in Banking and Financial Institutions, Palgrave Macmillan, London, doi: 10.1057/9781137533845_5.
Guzman, M.G. (2000), “Bank structure, capital accumulation and growth: a simple macroeconomic model”, Economic Theory, Vol. 16 No. 2, pp. 421-455.
He, Z. and Xiong, W.E.I. (2012), “Rollover risk and credit risk”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 67 No. 2, pp. 391-430.
Hellmann, T.F., Murdock, K.C. and Stiglitz, J.E. (2000), “Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: are capital requirements enough?”, American Economic Review, Vol. 90 No. 1, pp. 147-165.
Horvath, R., Seidler, J. and Weill, L. (2016), “How Bank Competition influences liquidity creation”, Economic Modelling, Vol. 52, pp. 155-161.
Imbierowicz, B. and Rauch, C. (2014), “The relationship between liquidity risk and credit risk in banks”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 40, pp. 242-256.
Jarvis, D.S.L. (2002), “Vietnam's financial services sector: prospects for reform”, Policy and Society, Vol. 21 No. 2, pp. 42-64.
Jiang, L., Levine, R. and Lin, C. (2018), “Competition and bank liquidity creation”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 54 No. 2, pp. 513-538.
Jiménez, G., Lopez, J.A. and Saurina, J. (2013), “How does competition affect bank risk-taking?”, Journal of Financial Stability, Vol. 9 No. 2, pp. 185-195.
Joh, S.W. and Kim, J. (2012), “Does competition affect the role of banks as liquidity providers?”, 한국재무학회 학술대회, Vol. 5, pp. 1478-1520.
Kahn, M., Kandel, S. and Sarig, O. (2002), “Real and nominal effects of Central Bank monetary policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 49 No. 8, pp. 1493-1519.
Kahn, C., Pennacchi, G. and Sopranzetti, B. (2005), “Bank consolidation and the dynamics of consumer loan interest rates”, The Journal of Business, Vol. 78 No. 1, pp. 99-134.
Kashyap, A.K. and Stein, J.C. (1995), “The impact of monetary policy on bank balance sheets”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 42, pp. 151-195.
Kashyap, A.K., Rajan, R. and Stein, J.C. (2002), “Banks as liquidity providers: an explanation for the coexistence of lending and deposit-taking”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 57 No. 1, pp. 33-73.
King, M.R. (2013), “The Basel iii net stable funding ratio and bank net interest margins”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 37 No. 11, pp. 4144-4156.
Kiviet, J.F. (2020), “Microeconometric dynamic panel data methods: model specification and selection issues”, Econometrics and Statistics, Vol. 13, pp. 16-45.
Klein, P.-O. and Weill, L. (2018), “Bank profitability and economic growth”, BOFIT Discussion Paper No. 15/2018, available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3207171
Le, T. (2019), “The interrelationship between liquidity creation and bank capital in Vietnamese banking”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 45 No. 2, pp. 331-347.
Le, T.D.Q. and Pham, X.T.T. (2021), “The inter-relationships among liquidity creation, Bank Capital and credit risk: evidence from emerging Asia–pacific economies”, Managerial Finance, Vol. 47 No. 8, pp. 1149-1167.
Lei, A.C.H. and Song, Z. (2013), “Liquidity creation and bank capital structure in China”, Global Finance Journal, Vol. 24 No. 3, pp. 188-202.
Lensink, R. and Sterken, E. (2002), “Monetary transmission and bank competition in the emu”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 26 No. 11, pp. 2065-2075.
Leroy, A. and Lucotte, Y. (2017), “Is there a competition-stability trade-off in European banking?”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, Vol. 46, pp. 199-215.
Love, I. and Martínez Pería, M.S. (2012), “How bank competition affects firms' access to finance”, Policy Research Working Papers, The World Bank.
Love, I. and Martínez Pería, M.S. (2015), “How Bank Competition affects firms' access to finance”, The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 29 No. 3, pp. 413-448.
Moslehpour, M., Al-Fadly, A., Ehsanullah, S., Chong, K.W., Xuyen, N.T.M. and Tan, L.P. (2022), “Assessing financial risk spillover and panic impact of covid-19 on European and Vietnam stock market”, Environmental Science and Pollution Research International, Vol. 29, pp. 28226-28240.
Naveed, M., Saif, O.B., Sindhu, M.I. and Sanaullah (2017), “Impact of bank competition on bank liquidity creation: empirical evidence from gcc and Asean region”, Journal of Business and Tourism, Vol. November Special Issue, ICCSS, Indonesia, pp. 395-412.
Nguyen, T.T.H. and Phan, G.Q. (2018a), “The impact of funding liquidity on risk-taking behaviour of Vietnamese banks: approaching by Z-score measure”, International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, Vol. 8 No. 3, pp. 29-35.
Nguyen, T.T.H. and Phan, G.Q. (2018b), “Monetary policy, bank competitiveness and bank risk-taking: empirical evidence from Vietnam”, Asian Academy of Management Journal of Accounting and Finance, Vol. 14 No. 2, pp. 137-156.
Nguyen, T.T.H. and Wong, W.-K. (2021), “Do state ownership and business environment explain corporate cash holdings? Empirical evidence from an emerging country”, Asian Academy of Management Journal of Accounting and Finance, Vol. 17 No. 1, pp. 1-33.
Nguyen, T.T.H., Moslehpour, M., Vo, T.T.V. and Wong, W.K. (2020), “State ownership and risk-taking behavior: an empirical approach to get better profitability, investment, and trading strategies for listed corporates in Vietnam”, Economies, Vol. 8 No. 2, pp. 1-22.
Perotti, E.C., Ratnovski, L. and Vlahu, R. (2011), “Capital regulation and tail risk”, De Nederlandsche Bank Working Paper No. 307, available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1951899
Petersen, M.A. and Rajan, R.G. (1995), “The effect of credit market competition on lending relationships”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110 No. 2, pp. 407-443.
Peydro, J.-L., Polo, A. and Sette, E. (2021), “Monetary policy at work: security and credit application registers evidence”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 140 No. 3, pp. 789-814.
Rauch, C., Steffen, S., Hackethal, A. and Tyrell, M. (2010), “Determinants of bank liquidity creation”, available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1343595
Repkova, I. (2012), “Market power in the Czech banking sector”, Journal of Competitiveness, Vol. 4 No. 1, pp. 143-155.
Roodman, D. (2009), “How to do Xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system gmm in stata”, The Stata Journal, Vol. 9, pp. 86-136.
Sahyouni, A. and Wang, M. (2019), “Liquidity creation and bank performance of Syrian banks before and during the Syrian war”, International Journal of Financial Studies, Vol. 7 No. 3, p. 40.
Toh, M.Y., Gan, C. and Li, Z. (2019), “Bank diversification, competition and liquidity creation: evidence from Malaysian banks”, The Singapore Economic Review, Vol. 65 No. 04, pp. 1127-1156.
Tran, V.T., Lin, C.-T. and Nguyen, H. (2016), “Liquidity creation, regulatory capital, and bank profitability”, International Review of Financial Analysis, Vol. 48, pp. 98-109.
Turk Ariss, R. (2010), “On the implications of market power in banking: evidence from developing countries”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 34 No. 4, pp. 765-775.
Ullah, S., Akhtar, P. and Zaefarian, G. (2018), “Dealing with endogeneity bias: the generalized method of moments (gmm) for panel data”, Industrial Marketing Management, Vol. 71, pp. 69-78.
Vanhoose, D.D. (1985), “Bank Market structure and monetary control”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 17 No. 3, p. 298.
Vo, X.V. and Nguyen, H.H. (2018), “Bank restructuring and bank efficiency—the case of Vietnam”, Cogent Economics and Finance, Vol. 6 No. 1, 1520423.
Wang, Y., Whited, T.M., Wu, Y. and Xiao, K. (2022), “Bank market power and monetary policy transmission: Evidence from a structural estimation”, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 77 No. 4, pp. 2093-2141.
Yang, J. and Shao, H. (2016), “Impact of bank competition on the bank lending channel of monetary transmission: evidence from China”, International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 43, pp. 468-481.
Yeddou, N. and Pourroy, M. (2020), “Bank liquidity creation: does ownership structure matter?”, The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 78, pp. 116-131.
Acknowledgements
The authors would like to thank Professor Nguyen Trong Hoai - editor-in-chief, anonymous referees and the handling editor for their helpful comments, which helped to improve the manuscript significantly. The third author would also like to thank Robert B. Miller and Howard E. Thompson for their ongoing counseling and encouragement. The authors would like to acknowledge the grant support received from Asia University, Saigon University, China Medical University Hospital, The Hang Seng University of Hong Kong, the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong (Project number 12500915) and the Ministry of Science and Technology (MOST, Project Numbers 106–2410-H-468–002 and 107–2410-H-468–002-MY3), Taiwan.