Impact of average daily rate on hotel’s newest atmosphere

Xuan V. Tran (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Kaleigh McCullough (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Makayla Blankenship (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Trista Barton (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Sophia Cohen (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Tabitha Harris (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Andrea Lopez (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Summer Simone (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)
Trace Bolger (Department of Commerce, University of West Florida, Pensacola, Florida, USA)

International Hospitality Review

ISSN: 2516-8142

Article publication date: 2 April 2024

185

Abstract

Purpose

This study aims to create actionable guidelines for pricing decision-making by employing game a theory matrix to forecast the correlation between the average daily rate and the latest ambiance of hotels.

Design/methodology/approach

Utilizing a vector error correction model, the research employs game theory to assess the influence of the average daily rate on the hotel's newest atmosphere during both peak season (April–September) and valley season (October–March).

Findings

Findings indicate that during the peak season, when the average daily rate rises in resorts and falls in suburban areas, the hotel’s newest atmosphere is at its best in both types of accommodations. During the off-peak season, the hotel’s newest atmosphere is achieved when both resorts and suburban accommodations increase their average daily rates.

Research limitations/implications

There are two study constraints. One is the assumption that hotel guests in both parties prefer not to change hotels, but in fact they would. Two is a limited sample of two resort and suburban markets.

Practical implications

This suggests that the hotel’s newest atmosphere can draw both leisure and business travelers to suburban areas during the low season and more leisure travelers to resorts during the high season.

Social implications

The study’s findings have implications for revenue related to the hotel’s newest atmosphere and cleanliness for both suburban and resort hotels, particularly when promoting tourism collaboratively.

Originality/value

The study provides valuable insights for hotel managers in analyzing pricing strategies using matrices.

Keywords

Citation

Tran, X.V., McCullough, K., Blankenship, M., Barton, T., Cohen, S., Harris, T., Lopez, A., Simone, S. and Bolger, T. (2024), "Impact of average daily rate on hotel’s newest atmosphere", International Hospitality Review, Vol. ahead-of-print No. ahead-of-print. https://doi.org/10.1108/IHR-12-2023-0064

Publisher

:

Emerald Publishing Limited

Copyright © 2024, Xuan V. Tran, Kaleigh McCullough, Makayla Blankenship, Trista Barton, Sophia Cohen, Tabitha Harris, Andrea Lopez, Summer Simone and Trace Bolger

License

Published in International Hospitality Review. Published by Emerald Publishing Limited. This article is published under the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY 4.0) licence. Anyone may reproduce, distribute, translate and create derivative works of this article (for both commercial and non-commercial purposes), subject to full attribution to the original publication and authors. The full terms of this licence may be seen at http://creativecommons.org/licences/by/4.0/ legalcode


Introduction

Inadequate comprehension of game theory poses significant challenges for pricing strategies in the hotel industry, particularly in shaping the newest atmosphere within hotels. Game theory operates as a contingency plan, where one player's strategy depends on the response of their competitive counterpart, influencing payoffs for both. Hotel managers, utilizing room occupancy and revenue, compare data with competitor reports to decide on optimal room rates for maximizing revenue. However, uncertainty arises after the competitor's response, creating variations in profits due to a disconnect from game theory.

Hotel cleanliness, a key attribute in hotel services, is crucial for guests, who gauge it through the hotel's average daily rate (ADR). Previous research indicates that ADR has both positive and negative effects on hotel cleanliness, yet the duration of this relationship remains inconclusive. Hotel managers, rather than overwhelming information, prefer decision clues, but limited research explores techniques for constructing such clues as a practical operation.

The research introduces two matrices utilizing indices, applying game theory strategies to predict the connection between ADR and the hotel's latest ambiance categorized by cleanliness. The Smith Travel Accommodations (STAR) report evaluates market share performance, while game theory strategies concentrate on best responses, dominant strategies and Nash equilibrium. Despite their shared objective of assisting informed decisions in competitive settings, STAR and game strategies do not align, creating a disparity between them.

Camarer and Johnson (1991) explain why experts, despite possessing substantial knowledge, often make inaccurate predictions, attributing this to the actuarial model. This model, coupled with a few clues, enhances decision accuracy. In the absence of clues, experts seek additional and costly information, relying on intuition.

The study's central question explores the condensation of key performance indices into matrices as cues, enabling hotels to forecast trends using game theory concepts. Matrices, constructed based on a sample of two hotels serving leisure and business travelers, represent Player 1 (resort hotels) and Player 2 (suburban hotels). The assumptions involve the presence of customer preferences favoring Player 1's hotels over Player 2's, with each player's matrix reflecting percentage changes in ADR. The main goal is to construct matrices for both players utilizing time series data derived from key performance indicators. These matrices, employing game theory strategies, seek to anticipate competitive dynamics throughout the high and low seasons of the hotel life cycle, offering valuable insights for decision-making to hotel managers.

Literature

Hotel key performance index (KPI)–average daily rate (ADR)

The hotel key performance index (KPI) serves as a monthly measure of the fluctuation in prices paid by hotel guests in a given country. It encompasses various weighted averages of hotel services, representing the overall spending of hotel guests. The KPI includes supply, demand, revenue, ADR, revenue per available room and occupancy.

The ADR stands as a pivotal metric for assessing a hotel's effectiveness in room sales, determined by dividing the total room revenue for a year by the number of room nights sold. ADR growth, denoted as the percentage change in ADR, serves as a crucial indicator of the harmony between hoteliers and guest satisfaction. This is particularly evident in criteria such as value, sleep quality, service, rooms, location and cleanliness for the hotel’s newest ambience as evaluated by guests.

In the context of game theory, the ADR percent change becomes a vital tool for decision-making. The matrix consists of four quadrants, each signifying different outcomes based on the choices made by two players regarding increasing or decreasing ADR.

Previous research highlights the impact of ADR on customer satisfaction, with price playing a significant role in shaping perceptions of quality. There is ongoing debate about how price influences these perceptions, but studies suggest that guests with higher service expectations stay at lodgings when paying more for accommodations. Additionally, room cleanliness, maintenance and staff attentiveness are directly influenced by ADR. The study employs a game theory matrix comparing resort and suburban hotels to uncover the key factors behind changes in ADR and cleanliness standards.

In summary, the text emphasizes the importance of the hotel KPI, ADR and ADR percent change in the hotel industry, linking them to guest satisfaction and decision-making through game theory. The research explores the nuanced relationship between ADR and cleanliness standards, shedding light on factors influencing these dynamics in resort and suburban hotels in Figure 1 (line 40, p. 5).

TripAdvisor hotel criteria – cleanliness to measure hotel’s newest atmosphere

TripAdvisor lists six hotel criteria: value, sleep quality, service, rooms, location and cleanliness. Hotel newest ambience by cleanliness, a crucial aspect of the hotel atmosphere, is a primary criterion for guest feedback. Studies by Lockyer (2003) and Lewis and McCann (2004) emphasize the direct link between cleanliness and the ADR, influencing guests' accommodation choices. The hospitality industry's core competency, highlighted by Espino-Rodríguez and Ramírez-Fierro (2017), attributes competitive advantage to the hotel atmosphere, particularly room cleanliness. Hsieh and Chuang (2020) underscore cleanliness and environmental quality as key factors shaping the overall hotel service experience. Zemke, Neal, Shoemaker, and Kirsch (2015) consider cleanliness a crucial amenity and strength for hotels.

Notably, housekeeping personnel constitute a significant portion of the hotel workforce, as indicated by Krause, Scherzer, and Rugulies (2005), and cleaning-related occupations contribute substantially to employment in France (Abasabanye, Bailly, & Devetter, 2018). Studies by Aguilar-Escobar, Garrido-Vega, Majado-Márquez, and Camuñez-Ruiz (2021), Dalci, Tanis, and Kosan (2010) and Jones and Siag (2009) delve into hotel room cleaning processes, cleaning profitability analysis and factors influencing cleaning productivity in hotels, respectively.

The research formulates the demand for the six criteria by considering two primary factors: ADR and guests' income, assessed through gross domestic product per capita (GDP per capita). GDP per capita represents the total value added by resident producers and taxes minus subsidies, divided by the mid-year population. The growth rate of income is quantified using the percentage change in GDP per capita. The objective of the study is to comprehend the connection between these factors and the demand for hotel criteria in Pensacola, with a particular emphasis on the growth of citizen income and comparisons to the US citizen index in Figure 2. (Line 42, p. 6).

Game theory

Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944, 1947 and 1953) laid the foundational principles of game theory with the aim of offering insights into decision-making and strategic responses for maximizing gains in uncertain situations. Game theory revolves around three fundamental concepts: best response, dominant strategy and Nash equilibrium. The best response entails a strategy that secures a player a greater payoff than the strategy chosen by their opponent. A dominant strategy ensures a player a superior payoff regardless of the opponent's choices, while Nash equilibrium signifies a scenario where mutual best responses coexist, indicating optimal strategies for both players.

Game theory employs mathematical models to explore scenarios optimizing variables associated with benefits. Integrating decision theory, general equilibrium theory and mechanism design theory, game theory, as delineated by Levine (2016), delves into decision-making intricacies, buyer–seller interactions based on prices and compensation mechanisms, respectively. Tversky and Kahneman (1992) expanded decision theory with prospect theory, considering risk, happiness and wealth.

Significant contributors like John Keynes (1936–2008) and Hurwicz and Reiter (2006) made substantial contributions to general equilibrium theory and mechanism design theory, respectively. Nobel Prize Winners in Game Theory (2014) highlighted game theory's diverse applications in economics, political science, psychology, logic and biology.

Despite its importance, game theory remains underdeveloped in tourism. Feeny, Hanna, and McEvoy (1996) argue for a comprehensive framework addressing issues, such as overexploitation and conflicts between stakeholders. Vail and Hultkrantz (2000) express reservations about cooperative games in mitigating conflicts. Nevertheless, game theory holds potential for insights and solutions in resolving these conflicts.

Williams (2001) emphasizes challenges in establishing a stable ecosystem in tourism due to cultural differences. He suggests adopting a Western cultural approach within a game theory framework, emphasizing the shift from agricultural production to facilitating public access to the countryside.

Challenges related to time series data in tourism and the application of game theory in decision-making for hotel managers are addressed by Camarer and Johnson (1991). They utilize matrices to assist decision-making processes in suburban and resort hotels, with a focus on ADR decisions.

The study develops a game theory model for two players (suburban and resort) in the tourism sector, aiming to overcome challenges by revising ADRs and providing key clues in matrix tables. The study tests hypotheses on the correlation between hotel atmosphere and ADR fluctuations during the year and in high and low seasons. Results confirm significant changes in hotel atmosphere levels based on ADR fluctuations, supporting the proposed hypotheses.

Mossetti (2006) offers an example of applying game theory, particularly the prisoner's dilemma model, to assess social dilemmas in the context of sustainable tourism. This application centers on the uncoordinated choices made by self-interested, profit-maximizing players.

Despite its significance, game theory remains an underdeveloped area within the field of tourism. Feeny et al. (1996) argue that addressing complex issues, such as overexploitation and conflicts between more powerful and weaker stakeholders in recreational land use, requires a more comprehensive framework. Vail and Hultkrantz (2000) express reservations about the effectiveness of cooperative games in mitigating conflicts among landowners, tourists and the distribution of benefits. Nevertheless, it is evident that game theory holds the potential to provide valuable insights and solutions for addressing these conflicts.

Williams (2001) emphasizes the challenge of establishing a stable ecosystem in tourist settings, primarily due to cultural differences. He proposes adopting a Western cultural approach that involves studying cooperation and conflict within a game theory framework. Williams underscores the need to shift policy priorities away from agricultural production in favor of facilitating public access to the countryside, as restricting such access can lead to conflicts concerning the development and management of natural landscapes.

Another challenge within the tourism sector involves navigating time series data, which can obscure the relationships between tourists and property owners concerning benefits. Numerous researchers, including Buhalis (2000), Wang and Krakover (2007), Uysal, Chen, and Williams (2000), Milhalic (2000), Kozak (2001) and Ritchie and Crouch (2000), recognize the role of governments in enhancing destination appeal through support and funding. However, many of these studies overlook the inclusion of time series data in their frameworks.

To facilitate decision-making for hotel managers, who often prefer succinct guidance over extensive information, Camarer and Johnson (1991) employed actuarial models like regression equations to address why experts possess extensive knowledge but make inaccurate predictions. This study adopts a similar approach by applying game theory to decision-making processes within suburban and resort hotels in the United States of America (Figure 3).

In the model above, r4 > r3 > r2 > r1 represents relationships among decisions (Camarer and Johnson, 1991). Hoteliers making ADR decisions prefer using matrices as a guide rather than relying solely on their experiences (r4 > r2). Camarer and Johnson (1991) report that full-time radiologists are no better than advanced medical students at detecting lesions in abnormal lungs, suggesting that, in some domains, training, but not professional experience, improves prediction. The main reason for this is that professional experts, such as national tourism organizations, often make decisions using the configural rule. The configural rule posits that the impact of one variable on an outcome depends on the level of another variable. To address these issues, this study proposes two matrices: one for hotels in suburban areas and another for hotels in resort areas.

The study aims to overcome the aforementioned issues by revising the average daily rates in a 12-month moving average of hotels in suburban and resort areas from 287 rooms of five hotels in Pensacola, providing crucial cues in matrix tables for hoteliers to make informed decisions in the competition. In this study, two matrices were established for two key players: Player 1 (suburban) and Player 2 (resort), catering to target customers who are leisure or business travelers in Pensacola during the six-year period (2018–2023).

The results, presented through ADR percent change growth, were reported in four quadrants of the matrix. Hotel managers can gain a clearer understanding of strategies in the matrix tables, enabling them to forecast the best responses, dominant strategies or Nash equilibrium. The study then tested the values in the four quadrants of the matrix for suburban and resort areas during the two seasons through the following hypotheses:

RH1.

No significant correlation is expected between the hotel’s newest atmosphere and ADR, when there are fluctuations in ADR for suburban and resort settings throughout the year.

RH2.

A positive correlation is anticipated between the hotel’s newest atmosphere and ADR during the high season, when ADR increases in suburban areas and decreases in resorts.

RH3.

A positive correlation is expected between the hotel’s newest atmosphere and ADR during the low season, when both suburban and resort ADRs increase.

Methodology

Study sample

The study's sample comprises customers in the countries of Player 1 and Player 2. Data were collected from the World Trade Center and Smith Travel Research over a six-year period (2018–2023). The selection of Pensacola, encompassing suburban and resort areas, was motivated by the significant tourism potential with white-sand beaches and a thriving hotel business.

Matrices

Two matrices were developed for Player 1 and Player 2. Each matrix consists of two rows and two columns, representing an increase or decrease in the ADR for each player and their counterpart. Results based on cleanliness growth were reported in the four quadrants of the matrix. If the value in one quadrant surpasses those in other quadrants, it signifies the best response for that player. If values in one column or row exceed those in the other column or row, it indicates the dominant strategy for that player. If the values for both players are higher than those in other quadrants, it signifies Nash equilibrium for both players.

Data

Yearly data on ADRs, cleanliness levels and GDP per capita for the two players were collected from the World Trade Center and Smith Travel Research over the six-year period (2018–2023). The data were transformed into a 12-month moving average to address spurious issues in time series data. The percentage changes of the ADR for each player were calculated by dividing the difference for each year between two-year periods by the previous year to measure the growth rate.

Two peak and valley seasons were represented by a dummy variable, with 1 for quarters 2 and 3 and 0 for quarters 1 and 4. ADRs were set up in four quadrants for each player in the two game matrices, representing different scenarios. This resulted in eight variables in two matrices representing cleanliness levels for both players in the four quadrants.

Results

The matrices revealed significant variations in the hotel atmosphere's cleanliness levels when there were changes in ADRs from both players. The study's hypotheses received support, indicating distinct strategies for each player to maximize individual benefits. The pricing game between Player 1 and Player 2 involves rational individual actions, with each player choosing outcomes in their best interest.

Three matrix tables are presented below, proposing game theory strategies for the four quarters of the year between Player 1 and Player 2. Table 1 depicts the matrix for the entire year, irrespective of high or low seasons. Table 2 displays the matrix specific to the high season, while Table 3 reveals the matrix for the low season.

Comments: No Nash equilibrium is observed for both players. Hypothesis 1 has been validated.

In Quadrant 2 [0.08/0.41], Nash equilibrium is established, ensuring the highest cleanliness for both players to reflect the hotel's freshest atmosphere. When Player 1 increases its ADR and Player 2 decreases its ADR, both attain the maximum payoff during the high season.

Comments: Nash equilibrium exists in the high season. Hypothesis 2 has been substantiated.

In Quadrant 1 [10.17/82.17], Nash equilibrium is identified, securing the highest cleanliness for both players to mirror the hotel's newest ambiance. Increasing ADRs for both Player 1 and Player 2 in the low season leads to the highest payoff for cleanliness.

Comments: Nash equilibrium is present in the low season. Hypothesis 3 has been affirmed.

Discussion

In a win-win scenario, Nash equilibrium was observed during the peak season, where both players received the highest payoff. This equilibrium occurred when Player 1 and Player 2 either increased or decreased ADRs in opposite directions. In the off-season, a similar equilibrium was observed when the resort decreased ADRs and the suburb increased ADRs.

Cleanliness and sleep quality emerged as critical factors impacting a guest's decision to return. Positive experiences enhance loyalty, leading to future bookings and increased value from each guest. The study suggests that promoting hotels collaboratively during quarters 1 and 4, when room rates are lowest, can maximize promotional efforts.

Conclusions and implications

Situational manipulations, such as setting up matrices, were found to have a more substantial impact on information search than preferred cognitive styles. The study's findings have implications for revenue related to the hotel's newest atmosphere and cleanliness for both suburban and resort hotels, particularly when promoting tourism collaboratively. Despite two constraints, which include the assumption that hotel guests in both parties prefer not to change hotels and the focus on only two destinations in the tourist market, the study provides valuable insights for hotel managers in analyzing pricing strategies using matrices.

Figures

The average daily rate and percent change of suburban and resort in the US 2018–2023

Figure 1

The average daily rate and percent change of suburban and resort in the US 2018–2023

GDP per capita of Pensacola and the US country

Figure 2

GDP per capita of Pensacola and the US country

Relationships among decisions

Figure 3

Relationships among decisions

Percent change of cleanliness level without separating seasonal cycle

Resort ADR increasesResort ADR decreases
Suburban ADR increasesU1i (I,I)Uil (I,I)U2i (I,D)Ui2 (I,I)
−5.65−24.9−0.49−1.9
Suburban ADR decreasesU3i (D,I)Ui3 (D,I)U4i (D,D)Ui4 (D,D)
7.6−21.82.1−612

Source(s): Authors’ calculation

Percent change of cleanliness level in the high season

Resort ADR increasesResort ADR decreases
Suburban ADR increasesU1i (I,I)Uil (I,I)U2i (I,D)Ui2 (I,I)
−7.345−149.40.08330.418
Suburban ADR decreasesU3i (D,I)Ui3 (D,I)U4i (D,D)Ui4 (D,D)
1.4444.578−0.294−35128.8

Source(s): Authors’ calculation

Percent change of cleanliness level in the low season

Resort ADR increasesResort ADR decreases
Suburban ADR increasesU1i (I,I)Uil (I,I)U2i (I,D)Ui2 (I,I)
10.1782.171.6174.56
Suburban ADR decreasesU3i (D,I)Ui3 (D,I)U4i (D,D)Ui4 (D,D)
−29.6454.5−8.1964,872

Source(s): Authors’ calculation

References

Abasabanye, P., Bailly, F., & Devetter, F. X. (2018). Does contact between employees and service recipients lead to socially more responsible behaviours? The case of cleaning. Journal of Business Ethics, 153(3), 813824. doi: 10.1007/s10551-016-3390-5.

Aguilar-Escobar, V. G., Garrido-Vega, P., Majado-Márquez, J., & Camuñez-Ruiz, J. A. (2021). Hotel room cleaning: Time study and analysis of influential variables in a Spanish hotel. Journal of Industrial Engineering and Management, 14(3), 645660. doi: 10.3926/jiem.3441.

Buhalis, D. (2000). Marketing the competitive destination of the future. Tourism Management, 21(1), 97116. doi: 10.1016/s0261-5177(99)00095-3.

Camarer, C. F., & Johnson, E. J. (1991). The process-performance paradox in expert judgment: How can experts know so much and predict so badly?. In K. A. Ericsson, & J. Smith (Eds.), Toward a general theory of expertise, prospects and limits (pp. 195217). New York: Cambridge University Press.

Dalci, I., Tanis, V., & Kosan, L. (2010). Customer profitability analysis with time-driven activity-based costing: A case study in a hotel. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 22(5), 609637. doi: 10.1108/09596111011053774.

Espino-Rodríguez, T., & Ramírez-Fierro, J. C. (2017). Factors determining hotel activity outsourcing. An approach based on competitive advantage. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 29(8), 20062036. doi: 10.1108/IJCHM-05-2016-0291.

Feeny, D., Hanna, S., & McEvoy, A. F. (1996). Questioning the assumptions of the “Tragedy of the Commons” model of fisheries. Land Economics, 72(2), 187205. doi: 10.2307/3146965.

Hsieh, Y. H., & Chuang, I. C. (2020). Evaluation of key factors for service experience: A comparison of tourism factories and international tourism hotels. Tourism Economics, 26(3), 404436. doi: 10.1177/1354816619840099.

Hurwicz, L., & Reiter, S. (2006). Designing economic mechanisms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Jones, P., & Siag, A. (2009). A Re-examination of the factors that influence productivity in hotels: A study of the housekeeping function. Tourism and Hospitality Research, 9(3), 224234. doi 10.1057/2Fthr.2009.11.

Keynes, J. M. (1936–2008). The general theory of employment, interest and money. Chapter 19. BN Publishing, Hawthorne, CA, ISBN 9650060251.

Kozak, M. (2001). Repeater’s behaviour at two distinct destinations. Annals of Tourism Research, 28(3), 784807. doi: 10.1016/s0160-7383(00)00078-5.

Krause, N., Scherzer, T., & Rugulies, R. (2005). Physical workload, work intensification, and prevalence of pain in low wage workers: Results from a participatory research project with hotel room cleaners in las vegas. American Journal of Industrial Medicine, 48(5), 326337. doi: 10.1002/ajim.20221.

Levine, D. K. (2016). What is game theory?. Available from: http://levine.sscnet.ucla.edu/general/whatis.htm (accessed 22 April 2016).

Lewis, B. R., & McCann, P. (2004). Service failure and recovery: Evidence from the hotel industry. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 16(1), 617. doi: 10.1108/09596110410516516.

Lockyer, T. (2003). Hotel cleanliness–how do guests view it? Let us get specific. A New Zealand study. International Journal of Hospitality Management, 22(3), 297305. doi: 10.1016/S0278-4319(03)00024-0.

Milhalic, T. (2000). Environmental management of a tourist destination: A factor of tourism competitiveness. Tourism Management, 21(1), 6578. doi: 10.1016/s0261-5177(99)00096-5.

Mossetti, R. (2006). Game theory approach on sustainable tourism. In C. A. Brebbia & F. D. Pineda (Eds.), Sustainable Tourism (p.p. 337-340). Southampton, UK: WIT Press.

Nobel Prize Winners in Game Theory (2014). Available from: http://lcm.csa.iisc.ernet.in/gametheory/nobel.html(accessed 21 October 2016).

Ritchie, J. R. B., & Crouch, G. I. (2000). The competitive destination: A sustainability perspective. Tourism Management, 21(2), 17.

Smith Travel Research (2023). Available from: https://str.com/

Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297323. doi: 10.1007/bf00122574.

Uysal, M., Chen, J., & Williams, D. (2000). Increasing state market share through a regional positioning. Tourism Management, 21(1), 8996. doi: 10.1016/s0261-5177(99)00082-5.

Vail, D., & Hultkrantz, L. (2000). Property rights and sustainable nature tourism: Adaptation and mal-adaptation in dalarna (Sweden) and Maine (USA). Ecological Economics, 35(2), 223242. doi: 10.1016/s0921-8009(00)00190-7.

Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior (1st ed.). New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1947). Theory of games and economic behavior (2nd ed.). New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1953). Theory of games and economic behavior (2nd ed.). New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Wang, Y., & Krakover, S. (2007). Destination marketing: Competition, cooperation or coopetition?. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 20(2), 126141. doi: 10.1108/09596110810852122.

Williams, D. R. (2001). Sustainability and public access to nature: Contesting the right to roam. Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 9(5), 361371. doi: 10.1080/09669580108667408.

Zemke, D. M. V., Neal, J., Shoemaker, S., & Kirsch, K. (2015). Hotel cleanliness: Will guests pay for enhanced disinfection?. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 27(4), 690710. doi: 10.1108/IJCHM-01-2014-0020.

Further reading

Cavojova, V., & Hanak, R. (2014). How much information do you need? Interaction of intuitive processing with expertise. Studia Psychologica, 56(2), 8397. doi: 10.21909/sp.2014.02.652.

Hanak, R., Sirota, M., & Juanchich, M. (2013). Experts use compensatory strategies more often than novices in hiring decisions. Studia Psychologica, 55(4), 251263. doi: 10.21909/sp.2013.04.640.

Lewis, R., & Shoemaker, S. (1997). Price-sensitivity measurement: A tool for the hospitality industry. Cornell Hotel & Restaurant Administration Quarterly, 38(2), 4454. doi: 10.1016/s0010-8804(97)81475-9.

Lim, C., Min, J., & McAleer, M. (2008). Modelling income effects on long and short haul international travel from Japan. Tourism Management, 29(6), 10991109. doi: 10.1016/j.tourman.2008.02.012.

Mattila, A., & O’Neill, J. (2003). Relationships between hotel room pricing, occupancy, and guest cleanliness: A longitudinal case of a midscale hotel in the United States. Journal of Hospitality & Tourism Research, 27(3), 328341. doi: 10.1177/1096348003252361.

Nash, J. (1950a). The bargaining problem. Econometrica, 18(2), 155162. doi: 10.2307/1907266.

Nash, J. (1950b). Equilibrium points in n-person games. In Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, U.S.A. (Vol. 36 No. 1, pp. 4849). doi: 10.1073/pnas.36.1.48.

Nash, J. (1951). Non-cooperative games. Annals of Mathematics, 54(2), 286295. doi: 10.2307/1969529.

Nash, J. (1953). Two-person cooperative games. Econometrica, 21(1), 128140. doi: 10.2307/1906951.

Oh, H. (2000). The effects of brand class, brand awareness and price on customer value and behavioral intentions. Journal of Hospitality and Tourism Research, 24(2), 136162. doi: 10.1177/109634800002400202.

Parasuraman, A., Berry, L. L., & Zeithaml, V. A. (1991). Understanding customer expectations of service. Sloan Management Review, 30(3), 3948.

Reinhardt, D., & Hurtienne, J. (2023). Measuring intuitive use: Theoretical foundations. International Journal of Human–Computer Interaction, 131. doi: 10.1080/10447318.2023.2166204.

Tran, X., Dewi, N., Jenkins, Z., Tran, D., & Vo, N. (2016). Applying game theory and time series in Smith Travel Accommodation report (STAR). Advances in Hospitality and Tourism Research (AHTR), 4(2), 140161.

Xie, L., Li, Y., Chen, S. H., & Huan, T. C. (2016). Triad theory of hotel managerial leadership, employee brand-building behavior, and guest images of luxury-hotel brands. International Journal of Contemporary Hospitality Management, 28(9), 18261847. doi: 10.1108/IJCHM-01-2015-0004.

Corresponding author

Xuan V. Tran can be contacted at: xtran@uwf.edu

Related articles